INTEREST ARBITRATIONS

Decision Information

Decision Content

City of Seattle

And

Seattle Police Management Association

Interest Arbitration

Arbitrator:      Carlton J. Snow

Date Issued:   04/28/1988

 

 

Arbitrator:         Snow; Carlton J.

Case #:              06502-I-86-00148

Employer:          City of Seattle

Union:                Seattle Police Management Association

Date Issued:     04/28/1988

 

 

IN THE MATTER OF INTEREST ARBITRATION

 

BETWEEN

 

SEATTLE POLICE MANAGEMENT ASSOCIATION

 

AND

 

CITY OF SEATTLE

(PERC No. 6502-I-86-148)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

                        FINAL REPORT

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lieutenant John Carson

Association's Party Appointed Arbitrator

 

 

M. Carol Laurich

City's Party Appointed Arbitrator

 

 

Professor Carlton J. Snow

Neutral Arbitrator and Chairman

of the Arbitration Panel

 

 

 

Table of Contents

 

                                                                                                                        Page

  I.        INTRODUCTION                                                                               1

  II.      THE NATURE OF INTEREST ARBITRATION                            9

  III.     ISSUES IN DISPUTE                                                                       14

  IV.     PROCEDURAL RULING                                                                16

  V.      THE ISSUE OF WAGES                                                                  17

  VI.     THE ISSUE OF SPECIALTY PAY                                       68

 VII.    THE ISSUE OF CAREER DEVELOPMENT INCENTIVES       70

VIII.    THE ISSUE OF DISCIPLINE                                                          76

            AWARD                                                                                             87

 

 

 

 

IN THE MATTER OF INTEREST )

                   ARBITRATION                         )           Lieutenant John Carson,

                                                                        )           Association's Party Appointed

                     BETWEEN                                )           Arbitrator

                                                                        )

SEATTLE POLICE MANAGEMENT        )           Ms. Carol Laurich,

                   ASSOCIATION                          )            Employer's Party Appointed

                                                                        )           Arbitrator

                       AND                                        )

                                                                        )           Professor Carlton J. Snow,

                 CITY OF SEATTLE                     )           Neutral Arbitrator and Chairman

            (PERC No. 6502-I-86-148)                )           of the Arbitration Panel

 

 

 

 

FINAL REPORT

 

 

I.          INTRODUCTION

 

            This matter came for hearing pursuant to RCW 41.56.450

which states:

 

If agreement has not been reached following a reason-

able period of negotiations and mediation, and the

Executive Director, upon the recommendation of the

assigned mediator, finds that the parties remain at

impasse, then an interest arbitration panel shall

be created to resolve the dispute.

 

After the parties in this case found themselves at impasse

and participated in mediation, they presented the unresolved

issues to a panel of interest arbitrators.  There has been no

challenge to the statutory authority of the panel to resolve

the dispute.

 

            The arbitration panel has followed statutory requirements

set forth in RCW 41.56.450-41.56.460 as well as WAC 391-55-205 -

391-55-255 in deciding this matter.  By mutual agreement, the

City and the Association selected Professor Carlton J. Snow

as the neutral member of the panel.  Pursuant to WAC 391-55-205,

the parties appointed as partisan arbitrators Ms. Carol

Laurich to serve as the Employer's party appointed arbitrator

(after Ms. Lizanne Lyons, the original appointee, found it

necessary to become a witness for the City) and Lieutenant

John Carson as the party appointed arbitrator for the

Association.  Mr. James Pidduck, Assistant City Attorney,

represented the City of Seattle, Washington in the proceed-

ings, and Mr. James H. Webster of the Webster, Mrak and Blumberg

law firm in Seattle, Washington, represented the Seattle

Police Management Association.

 

            Hearings occurred on January 30-31, February 1-2, and

July 22-23, 1987 in a conference room of the East Precinct

Police Station located at Twelfth Avenue and East Pike in

Seattle, Washington.  The hearings proceeded in an orderly

manner.  There was a full opportunity for the parties to sub-

mit evidence, to examine and cross-examine witnesses, and to

argue the matter.  All witnesses testified under oath as

administered by arbitrator.  The advocates fully and fairly

represented their respective parties.  Ms. Wanda L. Williams,

Court Reporter of Kirkland, Washington, reported the pro-

ceedings for the parties and submitted a transcript of 1,495

pages in six volumes.

 

            The parties elected to submit post-hearing briefs in

the matter, and they submitted combined briefs of approxi-

mately 178 pages.  The neutral arbitrator continued to receive

evidence from the parties until December 8, 1987, at which

time he officially closed the hearing; but correspondence

from the parties and contact with them by conference calls

continued until December 30, 1987.  The parties waived the

thirty day time limitation for issuance of a decision by

the arbitration panel in this case.

 

            With its post-hearing brief, the Association submitted

three arbitration awards for consideration by the neutral

arbitrator.  In a letter of November 10, 1987, the Employer

objected to the Association's inclusion of two of the awards,

namely, Public Safety Employees', Local 509 and King County,

as well as the City of Walla Walla and Walla Walla Police

Guild.  It was the position of the Employer that those awards

amounted to submission of new evidence and tended to impeach

the validity of the Runzheimer Report (a report to be dis-

cussed later in this report) after the close of the hearing.

 

            On March 2, 1988, the Association submitted for consid-

eration by the arbitration panel a third award, namely, the

award in the City of Seattle and International Association

of Firefighters, Local 27.  The Association requested that

the arbitration panel take arbitral notice of this decision

and stated:

 

This is particularly true because, with respect

to the cost of living arguments advanced by the

City,    the panels [sic] and the Seattle Fire

proceeding had before them a record identical to

the record before the panel in this case.  Speci-

fically, transcripts of the testimony and exhibits

concerning the Runzheimer report offered in the

Seattle Police Management Association proceeding

were introduced as exhibits in the Fire proceed-

            ing.  (See, letter of March 2, 1988 from Ms. Weir

            to Professor Snow).

 

On March 11, 1988, the City of Seattle registered a formal

objection to the Association's submission of the IAFF award

on the basis of the fact that it was untimely.  (See, letter

of March 11, 1988 from Mr. Pidduck to Professor Snow).

 

            As a general rule, labor arbitrators have ignored evi-

dence submitted by one of the parties after a hearing has

been concluded.  The problem, of course, is that the other

party has been denied an opportunity to refute the new evi-

dence.  The more customary approach in arbitration has been

for a party desiring to submit new evidence to request that

the hearing be reopened, on the theory that it can be demon-

strated that the new evidence was unavailable at the time of

the hearing and is important to a resolution of the dispute.

If the evidence was available at the time of the hearing, of

course, it ought to have been submitted then, or at least

some substantial reason ought to be presented that explains

the nonproduction of the new evidence at the time of the

hearing.  (See, for example, Food Employers Council, Inc.,

67 LA 328 (1976); Madison Institute, 18 LA 78 (1952); and

Shopping Cart, Inc., 350 F. Supp. 1221 (1972)).  In the ordi-

nary case, additional evidence submitted after a hearing has

been concluded will not be considered by an arbitrator.

 

            A practice of long standing among some arbitrators has

been for them to research and take notice of other arbitration

awards.  The principle of stare decisis has not taken root in

labor arbitration, but awards of other arbitrators have been

utilized for guidance and in an effort to evaluate the reason-

ing of a decision maker that might have been applied to a

similar problem.  It is well understood that it is an arbi-

trator's responsibility to exercise independent and impartial

judgment with respect to the issues being considered, but it

also is prudent to give respect to the wisdom and experience

of others.  As one arbitrator has put it:

 

As to arbitral decisions rendered under other

contracts between parties not related to those

in    the case at hand, usefulness depends upon

similarity of the terms and of the situations

to which they are  to be applied.   They must

be weighed and appraised, not only with respect

to these characteristics, but also with regard

to the soundness of principles upon which they

proceed.  Certainly an arbitrator may be aided

in formulating his own conclusions by knowledge

of how other men have solved similar problems.

He ought not to arrogate as  his own special

virtues  the  wisdom  and  justice  essential  to a

sound decision.   (See, Merrill,  "A Labor Arbi-

trator Views His Work," 10 Vand. L. Rev. 789,

797-798 (1958)).

 

By enclosing a copy of decisional materials, a party merely

expedites the process of research by making readily avail-

able public documents which could have been cited in the

brief and secured by the arbitrator.  (See, RCW 41.56.450).

Use of decisional material from other arbitrators is not

unlike the concept of judicial notice.  It customarily is

assumed that a judge is free to take notice of the work already

done by the courts.  One treatise on evidentiary rules has

described    the process of "notice" as follows:

 

Usually there is recourse to statutes, court

rules, or cases that are referenced by citation

without  any  need  to  introduce  into  evidence

the original (or copies) of the pertinent materi-

als.   (See, Lilly, An Introduction to the Law

of Evidence,         p. 15 (1978)).

 

It, of course, is important to stress that taking "notice"

of previous awards does not mean that they have been used

in any precedential sense or that they have been treated as

new evidence.  Rather, the materials merely have provided

guidance with respect to the reasoning process applied to

similar problems and situations as those faced by this arbi-

tration panel.  Consequently, it is reasonable to conclude

that the panel properly may consider the awards to which the

Employer has objected.

 

            It also must be recalled that the Association vigorously

challenged the validity of the Runzheimer Report during the

arbitration hearings.  Consequently, for the Association to

include arbitration decisions that allegedly support its

position in this respect serves simply as further argument

on an issue thoroughly explored at the hearings.  Any sur-

prise the Employer may have suffered from the inclusion of

the material with the Association's post-hearing brief has

been  cured by the arbitration panel's consideration of the

Employer's rebuttal letters.  Accordingly, the arbitration

panel has considered all three of the arbitration awards

submitted by the Association with its post-hearing brief as

well as the rebuttal letter offered by the City on November 10,

1987.

 

            A procedural requirement has been set forth in WAC

391-55-220 which states that:

 

At least seven days before the date of the hear-

ing,  each  party  shall  submit  to  the members

of  the panel and to the other party written

proposals on all of the issues it intends to

submit to arbitration.

 

 

The Employer failed to comply with the regulation, and

there  is a dispute about the existence of a waiver that

would have released the City from compliance.  The City

sought a ruling from the Washington Public Employment Rela-

tions Commission with respect to the impact of the Associa-

tion's allegation.

 

            The Commission, in effect, returned the matter to

the arbitrator and offered the following guidance to the

neutral chairman with respect to the meaning of WAC

391-55-220:

 

            The  regulation  in  question  consists  of

two  sentences.   The  first  concerns  proposals

of parties, which must be submitted at least

seven days prior to the  date  of the hearing.

The second concerns issues, which must be iden-

tified  earlier  in  the  process.   The  reason

the  regulation  requires  that  all  issues  be

identified at  least  during  the  final  stages

of negotiations is to ensure an orderly arbi-

tration  process.   Proposals  may be exchanged

even after a dispute has been certified for

interest arbitration, but the final positions

of the parties need to be made known to one

another at a  set date prior  to hearing,  so

that preparation may be made for hearing.

 

            The question before us concerns the late

submission of proposals, as opposed to issues.

The  regulation  does  not   expressly   provide

a  sanction  for  submitting  a  proposal within

the  seven-day  period.   The  second  sentence

of WAC 391-55-220 only allows suppression of

an issue,  and then only when that issue was

not brought up at an earlier point in time.

That sentence is not applicable to the submis-

sion of proposals.  (See, Decision 2735-PECB,

pp. 3-4, 1987).

 

 

            The Commission was clear in its instruction that, for

any sanction for a late proposal to be appropriate, there

must be "demonstrable prejudice to the party receiving it."

(See, Decision 2735-PECB, p. 4).  If the late proposal were

the same as previous proposals, there is a presumption of

a lack of prejudice; and it would be inappropriate to impose

a sanction.  The Association failed to show demonstrable

prejudice in this case, nor did the Association establish

that it had been harmed in its ability to prepare its case.

It is reasonable to conclude that no remedy is appropriate

in this case and that the panel has jurisdiction to consider

all proposals submitted to it.

 

            The arbitration panel has complied with requirements

of RCW 41.56.460 in reaching its decision in this case.  The

framework for proceeding has been set forth in RCW 41.56.014

where the statute states:

 

The intent and purpose of  this chapter is

to promote the continued improvement of the

relationship  between  public  employers  and

their employees by providing a uniform basis

for implementing the right of public employees

to join labor organizations of their own choos-

ing and to be represented by such organiza-

tions in matters concerning their employment

relations with public employers.  (Emphasis

added).

 

The legislature has made clear that interest arbitration

has been established as an alternative means of dispute

resolution by recognition of the fact that public policy in

the state does not favor strikes by uniformed personnel.

Factors set forth by RCW 41.56.460 for consideration in

cases of this sort and which factors have been carefully

evaluated by the arbitration panel are as follows:

 

 

(1 )       The constitutional and statutory authority of the

Employer;

 

(2)        Stipulations of the parties;

 

(3)        A comparison of wages, hours, and conditions of

employment of personnel involved in the proceedings

with the wages, hours, and conditions of employment

of like personnel of like employers of similar

size on the West Coast of the United States;

 

(4)        The average consumer prices for goods and services,

commonly known as cost of living;

 

(5)        Changes in any of the foregoing circumstances

during the pendency of the proceedings; and

 

(6)        Such other factors, not confined to the foregoing,

which are normally or traditionally taken into

consideration in the determination of wages, hours,

and conditions of employment.

 

 

 

II.        THE NATURE OF INTEREST ARBITRATION

 

            Several observations about the nature of interest arbi-

tration will  help define the context for the decisions

reached by the arbitration panel.  Interest arbitration is a

process by which there is a binding determination of contrac-

tual terms.  While it is a modern day response to statutory

prohibitions against public sector strikes, interest arbitra-

tion has deep historical roots in the United States.  As

early as 1871 , the coal industry in Pennsylvania used the

services of a neutral third party to determine contractual

terms, including wages.  (See, Mote, Industrial  Arbitration,

p. 192 (1916)).  Depending on the pendulum swing, labor organi-

zations have vigorously disapproved of interest arbitration

or employers have objected to its use.  (See, Gershenfeld,

Thirty-sixth Annual Proceedings of the National Academy of

Arbitrators, p. 191 (1984); and Mote, p. 208).

 

            Most parties in labor-management relations are familiar

with grievance arbitration, a judicially oriented process

that attempts to define the rights of parties under an exis-

ting contract pursuant to well established standards of con-

tract interpretation.  Interest arbitration is quite differ-

ent.  Arvid Anderson, president of the National Academy of

Arbitrators, has offered the following observation about

interest arbitration.  He stated:

 

Interest arbitration is essentially a legislative

process, while grievance arbitration is essentially

a judicial process.  (See, 3 The Labor Lawyer 745 (1987)).

 

Interest arbitration focuses on statutory standards and is

based on procedures and criteria specified by the law.

Although mindful of the legislative cast to interest arbi-

tration, the Washington Supreme Court has sustained the

constitutionality of interest arbitration. (See, City of

Spokane v. Spokane Police Bureau, 87 Wash. 2d. 457, 553 P.2d

1316 (1976)).

 

            Interest arbitration responds to special problems of

collective bargaining that surface most uniquely in public

sector disputes.  On one hand, implicit in legislative enact-

ments in Washington with respect to interest arbitration is

the public policy that employes without access to ordinary

procedures in collective bargaining ought to be protected

against the unilateral imposition of wages and conditions of

employment by the Employer.  On the other hand, legislative

representatives have recognized that allowing these public

employes to engage in a work stoppage would give them an

unfair advantage over the public employer.  That is, some

public employes have a greater capacity for inflicting harm

on the public than do employes in the private sector.  More-

over, unlike employers in the private sector, public employers

ordinarily cannot put forth a persuasive  "inability to pay"

argument.  Thus, "unhampered by such market restraints, a

union that can exert heavy pressure  through a strike may

be able to obtain excessive wages and benefits."  (See,

Block, "Criteria in Public Sector Disputes:  Arbitration and

the Public Interest," Proceedings of the Twenty-fourth

Annual Meeting, National Academy of Arbitrators (1971)).

 

            The point is this:   interest arbitration is not intended

to give public employes every concession that they could

extract from a public employer.  Interest arbitration is a

substitute for a work stoppage in the sense that it provides

public employes an alternative forum in which to press those

issues they have been incapable of resolving at the bargain-

ing table.  It must be stressed that the interest arbitrator

is an extension of the negotiation process and, in part, makes

an effort to accommodate interests of the public employer

(and the citizens they represent) with interests of the

employes who have requested interest arbitration.  The

Washington legislature has concluded that interest arbitra-

tion is the best available alternative for balancing interests

of employers and uniformed personnel in the state.  By care-

fully delineating the issues subject to interest arbitration

and clearly defining statutory criteria to be applied by

interest arbitrators, members of the legislature have attempted

to protect the interests of all parties, including the general

public.

 

            It seriously misconceives the purpose and function of

interest arbitration to use it as a means of accumulating

guidelines with which the parties may settle later contract

negotiations.  That is not the purpose of interest arbitra-

tion.  Like a strike in the private sector, the outcome of

an interest arbitration is designed to be uncertain and to

provide both parties with a substantial risk.  The objective

of interest arbitration is not to produce predictability for

future negotiations.  Otherwise, the parties will view

interest arbitration, not as a last resort, but as the inevi-

table conclusion to virtually every negotiation.  If interest

arbitration is viewed as a place for collecting guidelines to

be used in future negotiations, there will be little incen-

tive for the parties to bargain toward a realistic settlement

because they will know that, ultimately, an interest arbitra-

tor will perform the job for them.  When the parties begin to

view interest arbitration as a place to garner guidelines for

future negotiations, "the leaderships of union and management

alike are relieved not only of the responsibility for ratifi-

cation or approval of negotiated contracts, but, more alarm-

ingly, relieved of responsibility for everything that is in

the contract, other than for formulating demands."  (See,

Zack, "The Arbitration of Interest Disputes:  a Process in

Peril," 41 Arb. J. 38, 42 (1986)).

 

            As a general rule, when one confronts an interest arbi-

tration situation involving a large number of unresolved

issues or containing economic proposals that are extremely

far apart, there is a suspicion that the parties are either

inexperienced with the process or that there has developed

a dependency-like reliance on interest arbitration.  It is

important to highlight the fact that using interest arbitra-

tion in the way previously described makes it a substitute,

not for the strike, but for the collective bargaining process

itself.  RCW 41.56.430 is clear about the fact that interest

arbitration has been designed as an alternative to a strike

by uniformed personnel and not as an alternative to diligent

collective bargaining by the parties themselves.

 

            It is correct that the goal of interest arbitration is

to produce a final decision that will, as nearly as possible,

approximate what the parties themselves would have reached

if they had continued to bargain with determination and good

faith.  But every interest arbitration decision must remain

"case specific."  It is detrimental to the bargaining relation-

ship of the parties for them to view interest arbitration as

a means of developing guidelines to be used in their future

relationship.    Only by making each interest arbitration case

"case specific" can the integrity of the parties' own process be

retained.  The purpose of interest arbitration is not to pro-

vide guidelines for future negotiation, for such an approach

removes the process from the parties' control in the future.

What an interest arbitrator does is attempts to inject some

realism into the parties  current agreement in order to pro-

vide a model for realistic negotiations in the future, but

the lesson for the future ought to be that the parties' most

predictable bargain can be struck by themselves at the bar-

gaining table.

 

            It is incorrect to conclude that this approach to inter-

est arbitration makes it a standardless procedure.  There are

statutory standards to be applied, and they have been set

forth in RCW 41.56.460.  Those standards, however, are to be

applied in a "case specific" and are not to be viewed as a

mandate for giving the parties guidelines to be followed in

future negotiations.

 

            Nor does an interest arbitrator in one case want to set

forth guidelines that hobble a future interest arbitrator

hearing a dispute for the same parties.  The statutory guide-

lines in Washington are set forth with sufficient specificity.

Some statutes, such as Washington Public Act 312, direct an

interest  arbitrator to give weight to compensation presently

received by the employees, including direct wage compensation,

vacations, holidays, and other excused time, insurance and

pensions, medical and hospitalization benefits, the continuity

and stability of employment, and all other benefits received.

The point is that this is a factor which normally and tradi-

tionally is taken into consideration when determining wages

and conditions of employment.

 

            This statute also directs the arbitration panel to take

into consideration the cost of living.  This standard, how-

ever, has not been defined by the legislature.  The cost of

living is a criterion that received special scrutiny in

these proceedings.  Presumably, the legislature intended that

money earnings would be inflated in an effort to obtain "real"

earnings, as the method customarily used in that process is

to rely on the Consumer Price Index.  Yet, the Consumer Price

Index is not really a cost of living index because it is not

responsive to purchasing patterns of a particular employe

during the relevant time period.  Despite its imperfections,

however, the Consumer Price Index has become the standard

method for measuring changes in the cost of living.  The

point is that, although "cost of living" is a statutory

standard to be considered in interest arbitration decisions,

the Consumer Price Index does not provide a scientifically

precise instrument for making decisions about cost of living

adjustments.  It provides a useful source of guidance but,

by no means, is definitive.

 

            Historically, a most important criterion and the statu-

tory standard set forth in RCW 41.56.460(c) is a comparison

with the wage structure of others.  As Arvid Anderson, who

chairs the Office of Collective Bargaining in New York City,

has stated:

 

The most significant standard for both [inter-

est]  arbitration  and  collective  bargaining

in the public service is comparability.  Com-

parability  relates  to  the  subject matter  at

bargaining and the question of with which em-

ployers  and  employees  the  comparison  should

be made.   (See,  3 The Labor Lawyer 745,  750

(1987)).

 

The legislature has directed that comparison be made with

"like personnel of like employers of similar size on the

west coast of the United States."  (See, RCW 41.56.460).

 

            Another important standard is the employer's ability

to pay.  That is, the interest arbitrator is called on to

give consideration to the basic economic circumstances con-

fronting an industry or enterprise.  The burden of proof with

respect to this criterion, however, customarily has been

placed on the employer, and it has been unnecessary for a

union to respond to such a standard, except as it has been

raised as an affirmative defense by an employer.  The

legislature in RCW 41.56.460, of course, has not expressly

stated "ability to pay" as a statutory standard.  The United

States Supreme Court has been clear about the fact that, if an

employer asserts the defense of "inability to pay" and refuses

to substantiate the claim, the employer may be guilty of the

failure to bargain in good faith.  (See, National Labor

Relations Board v. Truitt Manufacturing Company, 351 U.S.

149 (1956)).

 

            While statutory standards have been set forth in RCW

41 .56.460, there has been no legislative statement with respect

to what weight should be attached to any particular criterion

among the standards.  Arbitrator Arvid Anderson has observed,

in discussing a similar list of statutory criteria for inter-

est arbitrations in Michigan, "the enumeration of the criteria

seems designated not to limit the arbitrators, but to allow

them the broadest scope in considering whatever factors they

deem important in a particular case so long as they pay atten-

tion to the other factors."  (See, Block, "Criteria in Public

Sector Interest Disputes:  Arbitration in the Public Interest,"

1971 Proceedings of the Twenty-Fourth Annual Meeting, National

Academy of Arbitrators, 161, 167-178).  At the same time, it

is reasonable to believe that an arbitrator may not focus on

one statutory criterion, such as stipulations of the parties,

to the exclusion of all others.  In other words, the legisla-

ture clearly intended that, on the basis of evidence pre-

sented by the parties, an interest arbitrator carefully must

balance the values inherent in each of the criteria set forth

in the statute.  In this way, employes may be assured of

receiving working conditions and an income comparable to

those in their profession and locality, while the employer

may be assured that it will be able to recruit in the local

labor market.  Additionally, negotiating teams for both sides

will be given guidance with respect to the reasonableness of

their respective proposals.

 

            Interest arbitration requires a consideration of vari-

ous economic forces and circumstances confronting the parties

in their collective bargaining relationship.  By giving sub-

stantial weight to comparability data, there is an attempt to

give rationality to what is essentially a legislative pro-

cess.  Assuming the Employer is not a wage leader, compari-

sons have been attractive as a source of guidance in interest

arbitration because they "seem to offer a presumptive test

of the fairness of a wage."  (See, Feis, Principles of Wage

Settlement, p. 339 (1924)).  Even though agreeing about some

aspects of the entities with which the parties should compare

themselves, they have disagreed vigorously with respect to the

impact of the comparative data in the various jurisdictions.

 

 

III.       ISSUES IN DISPUTE

 

            The parties submitted the following issues for consider-

ation by the arbitration panel:

                                                                                                            Page

            1 .        Procedural Ruling                                                      1 6

 

            2.         The      Issue   of Wages

                        A.        Proposals                                                        17

                        B.        Discussion                                                      17

                                    (1)        Comparisons                                      19

                                    (2)        The "Labor Market"                        30

                                    (3)        Internal Wage Structure                    37

                                    (4)        Runzheimer Report                           39

                                                (a)        Evidentiary Problems            42

                                                (b)        Accuracy of the Report         43

                                                (c)        Application of the Data          48

                                    (5)        The Knowles Theory                         51

                                    (6)        A Wage Increase                               54

                                    (7)        Later Years of the Agreement          65

 

            3.         Specialty Pay                                                              68

                        A.        Proposals                                                        68

                        B.        Discussion                                                      68

 

            4.         Career Development Incentives                               70

                        A.        Proposal                                                          70

                        B.        Discussion                                                      71

 

5.         The      Issue of Discipline                                                     76

            A.        Proposal                                                                      76

            B.        Discussion                                                                  76

 

                             Placing Just Cause in Context                             77

 

6.         Award                                                                                     86

 

 

 

 

IV.       PROCEDURAL RULING

 

            The Association submitted a Motion for Default pursuant

to WAC 391-55-220, but this motion was withdrawn in the Post-

hearing Brief of the Association.  (See, Association's

Exhibit No. 7 and the Association's Post-hearing Brief, p.2).

A second procedural issue raised by the Association also

involved an interpretation of WAC 391-55-220.  In withdrawing

one motion, it was unclear whether the Association intended

to withdraw the second as well, since they were somewhat

interrelated.  As is clear from statements made in the

introductory comments of this report, the arbitration panel

has rejected the Association's position with respect to this

matter because the Association presented no evidence to

demonstrate either that it was unaware of the City's response

to proposals from the Association or that the City had taken

any stance in arbitration different from that taken during

mediation or that taken before the Executive Director of the

Public Employment Relations Commission.  Absent such demon-

strable prejudice, it is the conclusion of the arbitration panel

that  to prevent one party from presenting its case on the basis

of  a  technicality  would thwart the purposes of the statute

by denying the party access to an effective means of dispute

resolution, even though the party asserting the defense would

not have been hindered in its presentation of the case to the

panel.  Consequently, there shall not be any summary award

on the issue of discipline, the issue of overtime having been

resolved by the parties in later negotiations.

 

 

V.        V.   THE ISSUE OF WAGES

 

            A.        Proposals

 

            The Employer has proposed a wage increase of 1.5% to

take effect on September 1 , 1986 for lieutenants, captains,

and majors.  The City has proposed for the second and third

years of the parties' agreement that wages of Association

members be increased by 80% on the increase in the Consumer

Price Index (CPI-W) for the Seattle-Everett metropolitan

area, with a minimum increase of 1.5% and a maximum increase

of 6%.

 

 

            The Association has proposed that the employer provide

a wage increase of 10% for each of the first two years of

the 1986-89 collective bargaining agreement.  For the third

year of the agreement, the Association proposes that the

arbitration panel award whatever increase is necessary, up

to 10%, to overcome any remaining wage disparity and to pre-

serve the purchasing power of the members of the bargaining

unit.

 

B.        Discussion

 

            The parties have reached agreement with respect to

inter-city comparisons.  Those cities are:

 

            Long Beach, California

            Oakland, California

Portland, Oregon

Sacramento, California

San Diego, California

San Francisco, California

San Jose, California

 

 

The agreement about comparable cities, however, has not pro-

vided the source of guidance in this dispute that one might

have anticipated.  Obviously, stipulations by the parties do

not relieve the arbitrator of the duty to consider each of

the statutory criteria.  Recognizing this fact, the parties

have submitted evidence with respect to all the relevant

criteria; and they have disagreed vigorously with respect to

the appropriate weight that inter-city comparability data

should receive in their effort to negotiate an appropriate wage

rate.  The focus of the parties' dispute has been on which statutory

criteria should be the most influential wage determinants.

 

            The Employer has stressed the importance of the "cost of

living" criterion as well as local Consumer Price Index statis-

tics.  It is the belief of the Employer that those elements

should be largely dispositive of the wage rate determination.

The Association, on the other hand, has relied heavily on the

actual compensation figures from comparative cities in an effort

to establish that Seattle police managers are receiving inade-

quate compensation.  As previously indicated, however, the

statutory design has not expressly included more weight for

one criterion than another, supporting a conclusion that the

legislature expected an arbitration panel to balance all

statutory factors and to make no single criterion dispositive

of the outcome.  Analyzing the dispute in this way, it

becomes clear that neither the City nor the Association has

put forth a realistic salary proposal.

 

            In general, the Association has presented clear and con-

vincing evidence to demonstrate that Seattle Police lieutenants,

captains, and majors receive significantly less compensation

than do their counterparts in the comparative cities on which

the parties have agreed.  Currently a "top step" lieutenant

in Seattle receives less compensation in base monthly pay

than does a lieutenant in any of the comparative cities except

for Sacramento.  Those data are as follows:

 

            City                                         Monthly Salary

            San Jose                                 $4,176.00

            Long Beach                            $4,173.00

            Oakland                                  $3,985.00

            San Francisco             $3,976.00

            San Diego                               $3,734.00

            Portland                                  $3,724.00

            Seattle                                                $3,681 OO

            Sacramento                            $3,398.00

 

These data suggest that Seattle currently is below the average

base monthly salary of $3,880.00 by 5.4%.  It may even be mis-

leading to place Seattle ahead of Sacramento in this regard,

since testimony indicated that Sacramento lieutenants receive

21.34% educational incentive pay in lieu of higher base salaries.

(See, Association's Exhibit No.20, fn.3, and transcript, p.

155).  The point is that police lieutenants in the City of

Seattle receive at least 5.4% lower base monthly salaries, on

aaverage, than do their counterparts in comparative cities.

(See, Association's Exhibit 31, p. 1).

 

            The conclusion that City of Seattle police lieutenants

receive less actual compensation for their services than do

lieutenants in comparable cities receives confirmation by

studying data with respect to total compensation.  After cor-

recting an Association error with respect to the average for

net monthly total compensation among the cities, it is clear

that Seattle lieutenants receive 9.5% less compensation than

the average received by lieutenants in comparable cities.

(See, Association's Exhibit No. 31, p. 2).  Those data show

the following:

 

                 City                                                Net Total Compensation

            San Jose                                             $4,552.00

            Long Beach                                        $4,427.00

            Oakland                                              $4,136.00

            Sacramento                                        $4,081 .00

            Portland                                              $3,824.00

            San Diego                                           $3,785.00

            San Francisco                         $3,785.00

            Seattle                                                            $3,726.00

 

 

The data show that Seattle is below the average net total

compensation by $358.00 or 9.6%.

 

            Nor is the conclusion affected by comparing total hourly

compensation.  Those data show the following:

 

            City                                         Total Hourly Compensation

            Long Beach                                        $29.13

            San Jose                                             $28.63

            Oakland                                              $27.09

            Sacramento                                        $26.97

            Portland                                              $25.21

            San Diego                                           $25.12

            San Francisco                         $25.01

            Seattle                                                            $24.41

 

 

 

On an hourly basis, Seattle police lieutenants received 9.5%

less than the average wage of $27.74, or $2.33 below the hourly

average.  In the City of Seattle, police lieutenants receive

less total compensation on a monthly or hourly basis among the

comparison Cities.  It is also clear that police captains and

majors receive significantly less total compensation per hour

(9.3% and 12.8% less respectively) than is paid on an average

to captains and majors in comparative cities.  (See, Associ-

ation Exhibit Nos. 32, p.2 and 33, p.2).

 

            But is this conclusion significant?  The Employer has

argued that a correct interpretation of the data reduces the

significance of the conclusion.  Management has advanced

several arguments to diminish the significance of the Asso-

ciation's "actual compensation" data.  For example, the

Employer has contended that, if salary gains of police lieu-

tenants in the west coast cities are compared over a twenty

year period, Seattle lieutenants have benefited the most.

With a 1986 salary increase of 1.5%, Seattle lieutenants will

have received an overall percentage increase in base monthly

salary of 361% as compared with an average of 302% in com-

parable cities.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 133).  Those data

show the following pattern:

 

            City                             Overall Percentage Increase

                                                      From 1966 to 1987

            San Jose                                 331%

            Portland                                  325%

            Oakland                                  319%

            Long Beach                            318%

            Seattle                                                302%

            San Francisco             286%

            Sacramento                            278%

            San Diego                               264%

 

 

These data have assumed a 1.5% wage increase effective on

September 1, 1986.

 

            Making a similar argument, the Employer has pointed out

that, between 1967 and 1986, Seattle police lieutenants gained

53.4% in "real" wages, as compared with a 15.7% gain among

private sector employes.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 140).

(If the CPI-U is used to calculate salary gains for "groups,"

Seattle lieutenants have gained 45.4%, as contrasted with

15.7% among private sector employees). (See, City's Post-

hearing Brief, p. 62).  The Employer also has argued that the

salaries of Seattle police lieutenants were 146% higher than

the increase in the Seattle area CPI-W during approximately

the same period of time.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 141).

Finally, the City has observed that private industry settle-

ments (or at least those covering the 5000 or more private

sector employes) have been low, as low as 1.6% in the second

quarter of 1986.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 139).

 

            A review of the comparative data supports a conclusion

that the standard of living of Seattle police lieutenants has

improved during the past twenty years. They also suggest that

gains by lieutenants in "real" compensation have exceeded

those of other employe groups during the same period of time.

What the data fail to establish, however, is that the

Employer paid Seattle police lieutenants an appropriate wage

in 1967. On the contrary, the historical comparison sup-

ports a different conclusion.  The data show the following

pattern:

 

            City                                         1966-67

            San Francisco             $1,029.00

            San Diego                               $1,027.00

            Long Beach                            $999.00

            San Jose                                 $968.00

            Oakland                                  $950.00

            Sacramento                            $900.00

            Portland                                  $877.00

            Seattle                                                $810.00

 

 

With an average at that time of $964.00, the data show that

Seattle police lieutenants received 19% less than an average

base monthly wage for the comparative cities.  In other words,

the data have not dispelled the Association's contention that

salaries of Seattle police lieutenants remain disproportion-

ately lower than those of their counterparts in the stipulated

cities.  The data may only prove that Seattle police lieuten-

ants were not appropriately compensated in 1967 and gradually

have overcome much of the austerity during the ensuing years.

 

            Even though Seattle police lieutenants may have accomp-

lished relatively comparable wages by 1976-79, they began to

experience reductions in their  "real" buying power, as compared

with lieutenants in other cities.  At the time when the base

salary of "top step" lieutenants increased on average by 15%

from 1979 to 1986, personnel in Seattle experienced a loss in

"real" dollars of 1.8%.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 133 and

Association's Exhibit No. 18).  Those data are as follows:

 

            City                                         Base Salary "Top Step"

                                                                        Lieutenant

                                                            1979-86 Differential

                                                            (1967 Dollars)

 

            San Diego                                           + 38.4%

            San Jose                                             + 19.6%

            Sacramento                                        + 17.9%

            Portland                                              + 15.7%

            Long Beach                                        + 7.2%

            San Francisco                         +  5.7%

            Oakland                                              +  2.8%

            Seattle                                                            - 1.8%

 

 

These data diminish the impact of the low settlements reached

in the private sector on a national level.  The City's pro-

posal of a 1.5% increase would do little to alleviate the

disparity which has been demonstrated by the Association.

 

            Although perhaps obvious, it probably should be pointed

out that the arbitrator has focused on "top step" lieutenants

with twenty years of longevity, rather than on captains or

majors.  It will be recalled that this was the focus of the

parties, and the Association maintained without rebuttal that

lieutenants comprise the majority of the membership in the

bargaining unit.    "S P M A  longevity averages in excess

of 20 years.   Moreover, . . . the lieutenant's salary effec-

tively determines the salaries of the two higher ranks."

(See, Association's Post-hearing Brief, p. 14).  It must also

be noted that, in those cities with "calendar year" agree-

ments, average salaries provided by the parties have been

used.  An attempt has been made to    weigh , as relevant,

other factors influencing the meaning of the economic data,

such as the receipt of holiday or education incentive pay by

some police lieutenants.

 

            As previously noted, a "top step" lieutenant in Seattle

receives less or next to less than similar personnel in dif-

ferent area cities.  (See, Association's Exhibit No. 31).

Assuming that, with an educational incentive, Sacramento pro-

vides monthly compensation of $4,123.00, Seattle clearly

ranks last.  If one were to adopt the City's wage proposal,

it would affect the comparability pattern the following way:

 

            City                             Comparison with City's Proposal

            San Jose                                 $4,176.00

            Long Beach                            $4,173.00

            Oakland                                  $3,981.00

            San Francisco             $3,976.00

            Seattle                                                $3,736.00

            San Diego                               $3,734.00

            Portland                                  $3,724.00

            Sacramento                            $3,398.00 (or $4,123.00

                                                            with education incentive)

 

If one were to adopt the Association's wage proposal, it

would have the following impact on base monthly salary of "top

step" lientenants in comparison with comparable cities:

 

            City                             Comparison with Association's

                                                            Proposal

 

            San Jose                                 $4,176.00

            Long Beach                            $4,173.00

            Seattle                                                $4,050.00

            Oakland                                  $3,981 .00

            San Francisco             $3,976.00

            San Diego                               $3,734.00

            Portland                                  $3,724.00

            Sacramento                            $3,398.00 ($4,123.00 with

                                                            education incentive)

 

If one were to compute an average salary in the comparable

cities and exclude the City of Portland, it would produce a

figure of $3,906.00.  If one were to include Sacramento's

education incentive pay while again excluding Portland, the

average salary would be $4,027.00.  The average salary in

all comparison cities is $3,880.00, or $3,984.00 if one

includes Sacramento's education incentive pay.

 

            These data show that the City's proposed wage would give

"top step" Seattle police lieutenants a wage that would be 4.6%

lower than the average compensation received by lieutenants in

comparable cities located only in California.  If Sacramento's

salaries include the education incentive pay received by "top

step" lieutenants with twenty years of experience, the

differential would increase to 7.8%.  If one focuses on the

average salary paid in all comparative cities, the Employer

has proposed to pay Seattle police lieutenants 3.9% less than

the average comparable cities, or 6.6% less if Sacramento's

education incentive pay is included.  The Employer has

offered its "top step" lieutenants in Seattle a wage of

.3% lower than police lieutenants received in Portland,

Oregon.

 

            The Association, on the other hand, has proposed a 10%

wage increase.  That would produce compensation of $4,050.00

for a "top step" lieutenant.  This would mean a Seattle

police lieutenant would receive 3.7% more compensation than

the average received in California comparative cities, or

.6% more with the Sacramento education incentive adjustment.

When the Association's proposal is compared with the average

received in all comparative cities, Seattle police lieutenants

would receive 4.4% more compensation than the average wage,

or 1.7% more with the Sacramento education incentive adjust-

ment.  The Association has proposed that Seattle lieutenants

receive 8.8% more compensation than is paid to lieutenants in

Portland.

 

            It has been most useful to examine data with respect to

total compensation which the parties have submitted to the

arbitration panel.  Of importance has been a comparative

approach to the "hourly wages" data.  The arbitrator has

attempted to make a comparison of the total hour compensation

for the proposal of each party, excluding consideration of

the Association's career incentive pay and tuition reim-

bursement proposals.  Data from the Association's Exhibit

Nos. 28 and 29 have been used in an effort to avoid any

premature application of cost-of-living figures, before those

data have been analyzed in the report.  An evaluation of the

data provide the following pattern:

 

                                                            Current           City's              Association's

                                                                        Proposal          Proposal

 

Monthly Salary                                  $3,681 .00       $3,736.00        $4,050.00

Medical                                              $116.00           $231 .00          $226.0O

Dental                                                 $40.00 $44.00 $44.00

Educational                                         0                      0                      0

Longevity                                           0                      0                      0

Other                                                  0                      0                      0

Total Monthly Compensation           $3,947.00        $4,011.00        $4,325.00

Minus Pension of 6% Salary            $3,726.00        $3,787.00        $4,082.00

Net Hours                                           $1,832             $1,832             $1,832

Total Hourly Compensation  $24.41             $24.81             $26.74

 

 

            Comparing current rates with those that have been proposed

by the parties, one sees the following pattern:

 

                                                                        City's                                      Association' s

Cities              Current                       Cities              Proposal           Cities            Proposal

Long Beach    $29.13             Long Beach    $29.13             Long Beach    $29.13

San Jose           28.63             San Jose           28.63             San Jose           28.63

Oakland            27.09             Oakland            27.09             Oakland            27.09

Sacramento      26.97             Sacramento      26.97             Sacramento      26.97

Portland            25.21             Portland            25.21            Seattle                          26.76

San Diego         25.12             San Diego         25.12

San Francisco  25.01              San Francisco  25.01              Portland            25.21

                                                                                                San Diego         25.12

Seattle                          24.41             Seattle              24.81             San Francisco  25.01

 

 

As contrasted with the City's proposed hourly wage of $24.81

and the Association's rate of $26.74, the average hourly

wage in comparative cities, excluding Portland, is $26.99

or $26.74 in all comparative cities.  These figures show

that, according to the City's proposal, Seattle police lieu-

tenants would receive 8.8% less total hour compensation for

their services than do lieutenants in the stipulated California

cities.  Seattle lieutenants would receive 7.8% less compen-

sation than the average wage received in all comparative

cities.  They would receive 1.6% less compensation, if the

City's proposal were adopted, than do police lieutenants in

Portland, Oregon.

 

            Using the Association's salary  proposal  and

excluding its career incentive pay and tuition reimbursement

proposals, Seattle police lieutenants would be paid .9% less

than their counterparts in California comparative cities.  They

would receive precisely the hourly wage of all the comparative

cities without regard to any other factors.  They also would

receive 6.1% more compensation than do police lieutenants in

Portland, Oregon.

 

            As indicated earlier in the report, comparability data

are exceedingly important in interest arbitration.  There is

a sense of fairness about such information.  It must also be

recognized that police managers in larger cities clearly face

responsibilities and work related pressures not experienced

by managers of smaller police departments.  It would be

imprudent to attempt to determine a fair wage without giving

substantial consideration to what other similarly situated

police officers are paid for their services.  As already

made clear, the statute requires that economic comparisons

be made between employers of similar size.

 

            Yet, neither comparability data nor the stipulations of

the parties are dispositive of the issue.  The statute has

set forth a number of standards to be considered, employing

such other factors which are normally or traditionally taken

into consideration in the determination of wages.  Implicit

in the statute is a legislative recognition that it would be

too simplistic merely to compare wages paid in large cities

along the west coast, without acknowledging that different

economic conditions may prevail among them.  Thus, the legisla-

ture has instructed arbitration panels to consider factors such

as the cost-of-living or traditional factors such as the dyna-

mics of the local labor market and the impact of a "labor area."

 

            The U.S. Department of Labor, Employment and Training

Administration has defined "labor area"  as follows:

 

A "labor area"  consists of a central city or

cities  and  the  surrounding  territory  within

commuting distance.  It is an economically inte-

grated  geographical  unit within which workers

may readily change jobs without changing their

place of residence.   (See,  U.S.  Department of

Labor, "Area Trends in Employment and Unemploy-

ment," GPO, p. 13 (1975)).

 

Recognizing that there have been many definitions of "labor

market," the arbitrator has used the term with reference to a

particular geographical area within which a group of employers

and wage earners   buy and sell services.  It, like the cost-

of-living concept, is not dispositive and cannot be relied on

for unerring accuracy.  The concept of "labor market," how-

ever, is still a useful one and provides another source of

guidance in the determination of wages.

 

            One reason an analysis of "local labor market" data is

useful is because such comparisons allow the arbitration

panel to consider salaries of employes who work under the

same state laws, taxing systems, and relative economic con-

ditions.  Additionally, the employer has a legitimate concern

in paying wages that are sufficiently high to attract quali-

fied employes, while maintaining a wage rate that is not

inequitable or exorbitant as viewed by other city employes

or the general public.  It is in a consideration of "local

labor market" data as compared with the parties' proposals

that it becomes clear that the Association has sought too

much and the Employer has offered too little.  Even consid-

ering the special nature and risks of job responsibilities

faced by managers in a large metropolitan police department,

the conclusion remains unaltered.

 

            It is essential to give consideration to the "local

labor market" data because of the fact that an agreement,

such as the one with the Seattle Police Management Associ-

ation, is not an isolated event but is linked with numerous

other economic forces.  It, of course, is important to look

at the "industry" as a whole, as defined by the comparative

cities about which the parties have agreed.  It is highly

relevant for management to be aware of what other cities

currently are paying personnel, and such knowledge should

have considerable influence on the wage the Employer is going

to pay.

 

            But a second important connection with economic forces,

one that links this labor agreement with others in the com-

munity, is a comparison of workers and employers in the same

local labor market.  Employers in the local labor market all

have a standing relationship to one another, and their rela-

tive position is determined by their respective wage scales.

Customarily, employers in a local labor market have attempted

to maintain their relative standing with respect to one

another and possibly to move up in the ranking.  There is

prestiage  to be gained from establishing a reputation as a

"wage leader" or, at least, being recognized as having a high

standing in the group.  Such prestige can be translated into

the pragmatic advantage of giving one employer the first

opportunity to hire the best applicants in the labor market.

For decades, it has been recognized that there is a fair

amount of stability to be found in local labor market wage

standings over a long period of time.  (See, Reynolds, The

Structure of Labor Markets, p. 24 (1951)).  Hence, it is

appropriate to recognize "local labor market" data as only

another source of guidance for the arbitration panel.

 

            In an effort to clarify the proposals of the parties

within the context of the local labor market, the arbitrator

has used those data provided by the parties to compare

Seattle Police lieutenants' base monthly salaries to

those received in other Washington communities during

the past two years.  "Base monthly salaries" have been

used because the parties did not submit total compensation

data for Washington cities.  Additionally, testimony at the

hearings indicated that police lieutenants in Tacoma receive

longevity pay of 8% of a patrol officer's base salary with

twenty years of service.  (See, Association's Exhibit No.

16 and Transcript, vol. 2, p. 146).  Consequently, conclu-

sions drawn from the data depend on whether longevity pay is

considered part of a Tacoma lieutenant's base salary, and

figures reflecting Tacoma's additional pay have been indicated

in parentheses.  The arbitrator did not receive evidence with

respect to what a patrol officer's base salary would be for

the 1986-87 year.  As a result, the 1985-86 figure of $217.00

also has been used to represent a Tacoma lieutenant's longe-

vity pay in 1986-87.   A review of the information shows the

following:

                                                                                                Percentage

     Cities                     1985-86                       1986-87           Increase

Tacoma                       $3,597.00                    $3,601.00        1.5%

                                    (3,814.00)                    (3,868.00)        (1 .4%)

Renton                        3,449.00                      3,553.00          3%

Bellvue                       3,448.00                      3,517.00          2%

Mercer Island            3,445.00                      3,538.00          3%

Auburn                        3,360.00                      3,410.00          1.5%

Everett                        3,268.00                      3,399.00          4%

Kent                            3,154.00                      3,217.00          2%

 

Average                      3,387.00                      3,469.00

                                    (3,418.00)                    (3,500.00)        2.4%

Seattle                                    3,681 .00

City's Proposal                       3,736.00

Association's Proposal           4,050.00

 

 

 

            The data just summarized in chart form by the arbitrator

show that Association members are relatively well paid in

comparison with police managers in this geographic area.  In

1985-86, Seattle police lieutenants ranked at the top of the

local labor market for police management.  Assuming a 1.5%

wage increase in the base salary of Seattle police lieuten-

ants effective September 1, 1986, this position of wage

leadership will continue.  Lieutenants in Seattle would earn

7.7% more compensation than the average wage of $3,469.00

received by lieutenants in Renton, Mercer Island, Bellvue,

Kent, Everett, Auburn, and Tacoma.  That amount would be 6.7%

more compensation if Tacoma's longevity pay were approved.

On average, Seattle police captains would earn 15.5% more

than captains in the relevant comparative cities.

(See, City's Exhibit No. 137).

 

            If the Association's proposed wage of $4,050.00 for "top

step" police lieutenants were adopted, Seattle police lieu-

tenants would receive 16.7% more compensation than the aver-

age received by police lieutenants in the local labor market.

Even adding Tacoma's longevity pay, Seattle police lieuten-

ants still would receive 15.7% more compensation than the

average of other relevant police personnel in Washington.

 

            Other local economic data have also presented a challenge

to the proposed wage increase of 10%.  An effort has been

made by the arbitrator to compare differentials between

Seattle police lieutenants  and selected managerial personnel

in Seattle.  The objective has not been to compare actual

salaries as much as it has been to determine the impact of

the parties' proposals on customary differentials between

Seattle police lieutenants and these other supervisors.  The

arbitrator has not received any data for 1986 and 1987, and

the figures for those years (as indicated by an asterisk)

have been approximated by applying the average 1987 increase

for local area public agencies of 2.2%, as indicated by earn-

ings received at the  time.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 138).

 

            A review of the relevant information shows the following

pattern:

 

                                                                                                Percentage     Percentage

                                                                                                Differential     Differential

                        License &       Electrical        Seattle            for License     for Electr.

                        Standards       Worker          Police              & Standards   Worker

Year                Supervisor      Supervisor      Lieutenant      Supervisor      Supervisor

 

1967                $755.00           $807.00           $810.00           7.3%               3.7%

1968                850.00             890.O0            945.00             11.2%             6.2%

1969                893.00             935.00             1,002.00          12.2%             7.2%

1970                954.00             1,011.00          1,137.00          19.2%             12.5%

1971                997.00             1,057.00          1,276.00          28.0%             20.7%

1972                1,031.00          1,094.00          1,320.00          28.0%             20.7%

1972-73           1,089.00          1,154.00          1,391.00          27.7%             20.5%

1973-74           1,149.00          1,370.00          1,485.00          29.2%             8.4%

1974-75           1,277.00          1,507.00          1,674.00          31.1%             11.1%

1975-76           1,432.00          1,818.00          1,877.00          31.1%             3.2%

1976-77           1,508.00          1,911.00          2,023.00          34.2%             5.9%

1977-78           1,641.00          2,049.00          2,201.00          34.1%             7.4%

1978-79           1,766.00          2,237.00          2,368.00          34.1%             5.9%

1979-80           1,946.00          2,470.00          2,610.00          34.1%             5.7%

1980-81           2,355.00          2,819.00          2,923.00          24.1%             1.1%

1981-82           2,550.00          3,126.00          3,166.00          24.2%             1 .3%

1982-83           2,660.00          3,236.00          3,372.00          26.8%             4.2%

1983-84           2,743.00          3,236.00          3,453.00          25.9%             6.7%

1984-85           2,825.00          3,383.00          3,619.00          28.1%             7.0%

1985-86           2,867.00          3,483.00          3,681.00          28.4%             5.7%

 

 

            A number of conclusions can be drawn from these data.

First, it is recognized that the qualifications would have an

impact on salaries paid, but some weight can be attached to

patterns that have emerged over a period of twenty years.

The data show that, during the past twenty years, Seattle

police lieutenants have earned on the average 26% more than

licensed and standards supervisors in base monthly wages.

While the City's proposal slightly exceeds this average at

27.5%, the Association's proposal would increase the differ-

ential to 38.2%.  Seattle police lieutenants have earned on

the average during this time period 8.3% more than electrical

worker supervisors in Seattle.  The Employer's first year

proposal would decrease this differential to 4.9%, while the

Association's proposal would increase the differential to

1 3.8%.

 

            Another employment factor normally and traditionally

taken into consideration in the determination of wages is the

internal wage structure of an organization.  It is appropriate

to consider a larger complex of rates within the police

department, recognizing that this wage structure does not

necessarily operate as a unit.  The point of the inquiry is

not to make an issue of any individual rate so much as it is

to focus on any job clusters that may be pattern makers and

also to be aware of any wage contours that may help clarify

an appropriate wage rate for members of this bargaining unit.

An effort has been made to compare base monthly salary differ-

entials between ranks within the Seattle police department

in 1985 with those differentials as they would exist under

each parties' proposal.

 

            Ms. Dwyer, Labor Relations Analyst, testified that the

chief of police as well as the assistant chief of police

normally received the same wage increase as that bargained

for nonrepresented bargaining unit groups.  The amount on

which the parties agreed effective September 1, 1986 was .5%.

(See, Transcript, vol. V, pp. 1055-1056).  In other words,

the 1986 figures which have been used for the chief of police

and the assistant chief of police have assumed a .5% increase.

The sergeant's salary figure has included a maximum longevity

payment (8% of a "top step" police officer's pay).  (See,

City's Exhibit No. 185).  The data are as follows:

 

                        9-1-85                          City's Proposal                       Ass'n's Proposal

 

Rank                           Salary                         Differential     Salary            Differential   Salary            Differential

Chief of

Police              $5,707.00        9.2%               $5,736.00        9.2       $5,746.00        9.2%

 

Assistant

Chief of

Police              5,225.00          7.4%               5,251.00          6.3%   5,251.00          [ -2% ]

 

Major              4,867.00          15%                4,940.00          15%    5,357.00          15%

Captain           4,233.00          15%                4,296.00          15%    4,658.00          15%

Lieutenant      3,681.00          12.5%             3,736.00          12.5% 4,050               22%

Sergeant         3,372.00                                  4,301.00                      3,391.00

 

 

 

These data show that the Association's proposal of a 10% salary

increase would nearly double the percentage differential between

the ranks of lieutenant and sergeant.  Without maximum longevity

pay included in a sergeant's salary, sergeants' pay would be

$3,905.00.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 145).  The differential

between the two ranks at that rate would increase to 30.4%.

 

            Between the ranks of major and assistant chief of police,

the differential would entirely disappear.  Majors actually

would receive 2% more compensation than an assistant police

chief.  Such an anomaly in the internal wage structure does not

provide a basis for withholding an appropriate wage increase,

but the data would simply provide yet another source of guidance

and highlight the need of an organization to maintain a reason-

ably rational wage structure between ranks within the department.

 

 

            The Runzheimer Report.   The comparative data with respect

to west coast cities generally have shown that the Employer's

wage proposal in this case will not place members of the bargain-

ing unit in a favorable position.  On the other hand, the Asso-

ciation's proposal is overly optimistic when tested against

economic forces in the local labor market.  Although these

comparative data are instructive, they are still incomplete.

Another factor that deserves consideration is information with

respect to cost-of-living.

 

            As a preliminary matter, the parties have argued vigorously

about the use to which the arbitration panel legitimately may put

cost-of-living data.  The Association has contended the Consumer

Price Index is primarily a vertical measure of purchasing power.

That is, it measures inflation for the time in one locale.  In

the Association's view, the most legitimate use for "cost-of-living"

data is to determine the amount of salary increase needed to

maintain the purchasing power of bargaining unit members during

the duration of a negotiated agreement.  It is the belief of the

Association that such data are misused for purposes of making

inter-city wage comparisons.  (See, Association's Post-hearing

Brief, p. 21).

 

            On the other hand, the City has argued that a "cost-of-

living" adjustment must be a factor in the wage determination

in order to attain salaries that are truly comparable to those

received in the stipulated comparative cities.  The City has

argued with great determination that the Consumer Price Index

should constitute the single most important factor in determining

salaries of police management personnel.  The neutral arbitrator

has concluded that the most reasonable  position does not lie

with either of these points of view.

 

            As previously indicated, the legislature has deemed it

appropriate to consider "cost-of-living" information as a factor

in wage determinations but has not mandated what weight is to

be allocated to this statutory standard.  (See, RCW 41.56.460(d)).

It is more appropriate to view Consumer Price Index data as

measuring purchasing power within an area, rather than changes

in the actual cost of living.  As one author has stated:

 

The CPI never has measured changes in the "cost-of-

living."  Neither has any other index.  From its begin-

ning, the design of the Consumer Price Index has been

a fixed-rate market basket, that is, an index which

has measured changes in prices of a few selected and

unchanging quantity of goods and services.  (See,

Ferguson, Cost of Living Adjustments, p. 33 (1976)).

 

            The fact that inflation is low in a particular geographic

area does not itself respond to the problem of an individual

who has been paid at an inappropriate rate.  There is no

logical link between the argument that there exists a low

CPI and the conclusion that the CPI should be the single most

important factor in the arbitration panel's determination.

 

            At the same time, the Consumer Price Index clearly is a

useful tool, although an imprecise one, in evaluating inter-

city comparisons.  For example, if wages in Seattle and

San Francisco have been approximately the same since 1967

but inflation was drastically higher in San Francisco than

in Seattle during the ensuing years, logically one can expect

that wages in San Francisco would have to increase faster

than those in Seattle in order for wage parity to exist.  It

is reasonable to conclude that, if dollars have greater pur-

chasing power in one city than in another, this fact ought

to be taken into account in determining an appropriate wage.

Accordingly, the CPI data may be used to indicate generally

how significant are the disparities in actual compensation

between comparable cities.  Nor has RCW 41.56.450 or 41.56.460

restricted the arbitration panel's use of the economic data

in the way suggested by the Association.  The CPI and other

inter-city "cost-of-living" comparisons could have relevance

and have been used in determining the appropriate wage to be

paid members of the bargaining unit.  It is important to

stress that the statutory criteria are not completely separable,

and no one factor can be relied on exclusively without some

recognition of the impact on other statutory criteria.

 

            The parties have argued extensively about the merits of

the inter-city  "cost-of-living" comparison that the Employer

presented in support of its position.  According to the

Employer, Seattle police managers are able to maintain an

appropriate standard of living with approximately 6.8% less

cost than they could were they to live in one of the compara-

tive cities.  (See, Transcript, vol. IV, p. 950).  Conse-

quently, the Employer has argued that this cost-of-living

differential should be computed into actual compensation

data in order to determine when true wage parity among the

comparative cities has been attained.  (See, City's Exhibit

Nos. 130 and 131; Transcript, vol. IV, pp. 50-52).

 

            The City's conclusion that Seattle's cost-of-living

falls below that of Portland and the California cities by

approximately 7% has been based largely on the Runzheimer

Report.  (See, City's Exhibit Nos. 109 and 127; Transcript,

vol. IV, pp. 950-52).  As a consequence, the parties spent a

substantial amount of time debating the merits of the Report.

They expressed strong disagreements about the worth and intel-

lectual integrity of the Runzheimer Report and differed

vigorously with respect to its usefulness as a means for

determining cost-of-living differences in the comparative

cities.  The concerns focused primarily on three issues,

namely, (1 )  is the Runzheimer Report admissible evidence?

(2) how accurate is the City's 7% cost-of-living differential?

and (3) has the City inappropriately applied its cost-of-living

data to the wage proposal for members of the bargaining unit?

 

            At the hearing, the arbitrator indicated that, if the

panel decided the Runzheimer Report was hearsay evidence, it

would receive no weight.  (See, Transcript, vol. IV, pp.

928-29).  From an evidentiary standpoint, however, the

Runzheimer Report clearly is admissible for consideration by

the arbitration panel.  RCW 41.56.450 states:

 

The rules of evidence prevailing in judicial pro-

ceedings may be considered, but are not binding,

and any oral testimony or documentary evidence

or other data deemed relevant by the chairman

of  the  arbitration panel  may  be  received  in

evidence.

 

It is recognized that the Runzheimer Report is not without

problems with respect to hearsay evidence, but the arbitrator

has recognized that problem in determining the appropriate

weight to give the information.  As one court has observed:

 

Although the rules of evidence exclude hearsay

in a trial at law, the exclusion is not because

hearsay  is  entirely without probative value.

It has been said with some justice that charac-

terization of evidence as hearsay is in reality

simply a criticism of the weight that should

be given to it.  In an arbitration the parties

have  submitted  the  matter  to  persons  whose

judgment they trust, and it is for the arbitra-

tors to determine the weight and credibility

of evidence presented to them without restric-

tions as to the rules of admissibility which

would apply in a court of law. (See, Minneapolis

Honeywell  Regulator  Company,  54  LRRM  2660,

2661 (E.D. Pa. 1963)).

 

            Moreover, the Runzheimer Report clearly falls within a

recognized exception to the general rule against admission of

hearsay evidence.  Rule 703 of the Rules of Evidence for

the State of Washington provides for the admission of facts

and data reasonably relied on by experts in a particular

field to form opinions and inferences.  The Employer  laid an

adequate foundation to establish that Mr. Richard Schneider,

Vice-president of Living Cost Services for Runzheimer and

Company, is an expert in the field of  cost-of-living analysis.

(See, Transcript, vol. III, pp. 643-52).  Mr. Schneider based

his testimony on data and information which he routinely

uses in measuring "cost-of-living" differentials between

cities.  Cost-of-living factors unquestionably are relevant

in this arbitration, and the only substantial question is to

what extent.  Because the Runzheimer Report would be admitted

as evidence in a court of law in the State of Washington, the

neutral arbitrator has concluded that the Runzheimer Report

is admissible as evidence which the arbitration panel may

consider in its determination.

 

            A far more difficult question involves the appropriate

weight to be accorded the Runzheimer Report.  In other words,

the data used by the Runzheimer Company may be generally reli-

able.  "Cost-of-living" analysis is not merely a computa-

tional exercise.  Such an analysis requires that facts be

manipulated in order to be able to draw useful inferences.

Accordingly, the probative value of the report is subject to

challenge on at least two grounds, namely, (1 ) whether

Runzheimer's methodology is theoretically sound; and (2)

whether Runzheimer's data collection techniques are entirely

reliable.

 

            The Employer has argued that the Runzheimer Report is an

uncommonly accurate source of "cost-of-living" data because

it has been tailored specifically to the lifestyles and cir-

cumstances of Seattle Police management personnel.  In other

words, management maintains that Runzheimer, in comparing

members of the bargaining unit to their counterparts in the

comparative cities, took into account what individual income

levels were, whether individuals rented or owned homes, the

location of their homes, and what constituted the appropriate

"market basket" of goods and services for an individual making

$44,000.00 a year.  Additionally, the Report examined auto-

mobile and home maintenance costs, taxes, and other factors

relevant to developing a "standard of living prototype" for

members of the bargaining unit.  (See, Transcript, vol. III,

pp. 667-673).  The "Runzheimer" method, then, called for

representatives of the company to determine what it cost in

January, 1987 to maintain this standard of living in each

city and concluded that the average cost of living in Seattle

is approximately 7% lower than in the comparative cities

studied by the parties.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 7).

In response, the Association returned the volleys over

the net and added a few serves of its own.  The Association

persistently challenged the theoretical basis of the Runzheimer

Report in several ways.  Of great concern to the Association

was the fact that it believed home purchase costs accounted

for a substantial portion of the higher cost of living that

the Runzheimer Report attributed to the comparative cities.

According to the Association, the Runzheimer Report considered

higher purchase prices of homes in California or Portland

without taking into account the equity element of home ownership.

 

 

Thus, the Association maintains that, for example, the Runzheimer

Report ignored the fact that a police lieutenant in San Jose

allegedly is wealthier in terms of his or her home investment

at the time of retirement than is a Seattle police lieutenant.

The Association pointed out that, in 1983, the Bureau of Labor

Statistics changed its measure of housing costs to correct

exactly this problem.

 

            In the Association's view, the Runzheimer Report failed

appropriately to take into account "shelter costs" in analy-

zing "cost-of-living" differentials, and the failure consti-

tuted a serious flaw in the study.  It is the contention of

the Association that, when home investment costs are separated

from "shelter costs," even the Runzheimer Report indicates

that the net annual living cost in Seattle is not appreciably

(about 1%) higher than that in other cities.  (See, Association

Exhibit Nos. 194 and 195; Transcript, vol. VI, pp. 1318-1326).

The Association, however,    maintained that no weight at all

should be accorded the data.

 

            Moreover, the Association has argued the Runzheimer

Report assumes that a police lieutenant would buy the same

type of house and lot in Seattle that he would purchase were

he to transfer to San Francisco.  It is the belief of the

Association that such an individual would not be able to buy

as large a house and lot in San Francisco as had been left

in Seattle.  In effect, the individual allegedly would trade

the large house for other alleged benefits in lifestyle that

San Francisco could offer.  But, the Association has concluded

that the comparisons of the "standard house of police manage-

ment personnel" in the Runzheimer Report have ignored the

economic phenomenon of substitution, namely, that one resource

will be substituted for another whenever substitution results

in a lowering of costs.

 

            The Association was thorough in demonstrating that the

Runzheimer  Report is not without its problems.  It, neverthe-

less, is the belief of the neutral arbitrator that none of

these objections completely undermines the validity of the

Runzheimer Report as a source of guidance in helping to under-

stand differences in inter-city costs of living.  First,

Mr. Vogler's testimony reasonably explained why the Bureau

of Labor Statistics changed its procedures with respect to

the Consumer Price Index.  He viewed the Consumer Price Index

as a vertical measure of prices in one area for the time.  In

assuming that people would buy a house every year, computa-

tions in the Consumer Price Index overstated the true rate of

inflation.  Accordingly, a "rental" equivalency method alleg-

edly measures with greater accuracy shelter costs on an annual

basis.  This same problem allegedly does not exist in the

Runzheimer Report because it presents a true inter-city cost-

of-living comparison, that is, a horizontal measure of cost

of living in several locations at a given point in time.

(See, Transcript, vol. VI, p. 1487).  For example, the fact

that a police lieutenant living in San Jose, California has

amassed more equity at retirement than has a lieutenant in

Seattle does not change the fact that the individual in San Jose

must pay more to maintain a certain standard of living.  The

Association's argument appeared to assume that such an indi-

vidual would retire in an area of lower housing costs or

obtain a "home equity" loan in order to be able to consume his or

her alleged greater wealth.  There, however, was no showing

that such assumptions are logically necessary.

 

            Similarly, the fact that an individual is unable to pay

for as large a house in San Francisco, California as he or

she could purchase in Seattle, Washington appears to support,

not undermine, the supposition that it costs more to live a

particular lifestyle in San Francisco than it does in Seattle.

Further, even if the panel were to accept the Association's

contention that a police manager in California will retire

wealthier than one in Seattle, there simply is no direct

relationship between how much wealth an individual accumu-

lates over a lifetime and how much it costs that individual

to maintain a certain standard of living.  Finally, the

"fixed market basket" approach used by Runzheimer personnel

is similar to that used by the Bureau of Labor Statistics

in computing its Urban Family Budget, as well as by the

American Chamber of Commerce Researchers' Association, and

by the Associates for International Research, Inc.  (See,

Transcript, vol. III, pp. 431-434, and City's Exhibit Nos.

80A and 80B).  It is a traditional method of data gathering

and one of the few available methods for making inter-city

"cost-of-living" comparisons.

 

            On the other hand, the Association's other objections

to the Runzheimer Report cannot be answered so easily.  At

the arbitration hearing, the Association pointed out that

the Employer had refused its request to review all written

and oral communications between the City and personnel of

the Runzheimer Company, as well as any earlier versions of

drafts of the Report, and all mathematical formulae and

factual data used to prepare the report.  (See, Association's

Exhibit No. 114 and Transcript, vol. IV, p. 862).  The

Association contended that the Employer's refusal to provide

the information limited the Association's ability to cross-

examine witnesses and adequately to prepare its case with

respect to the Report.  (See, Transcript, vol. IV, p. 863).

The Employer maintained that the Association's requests

were made on unreasonably short notice and lacked sufficient

specificity.

 

            The arbitrator has concluded that the Employer complied

with the Association's request to the extent that it was able.

(See, City's Exhibit Nos. 112 and 113, and Association's Exhibit

Nos. 114 and 115).  The fact remains, however, that much of the

data and formulae used to prepare the Runzheimer Report was

unavailable to the Association, either because the Runzheimer

Company characterized the information as "proprietary,  or because

some of the data were inherently historical in nature.  (See, Tran-

script, vol. IV, p. 806). The Association received considerable

latitude through the process of cross-examination to bring

to light serious methodological flaws in the study.

 

            In fact, the Association established several difficulties

with the Report.  For example, underlying data with respect

to "Seattle area homes" used by the Runzheimer company to

compare the price of a 2000 square foot Seattle home with a

2000 square foot home in comparative cities either had been

destroyed or, otherwise, were unavailable.  (See, Transcript,

vol. IV, pp. 86-87).  Likewise, the Association was unable to

test the evidentiary soundness of the ten comparable Seattle

homes chosen for the study because the actual homes compared

were not known.  There were numerous questions which the

Association would like to have answered with respect to this

matter.  For example, were the homes Runzheimer personnel

chose located in appropriate neighborhoods?  Were all the

homes in the same condition?  Were they more or less than

2000 square feet, and if so, by how much?  Because the speci-

fic sources of information used for the Runzheimer Report

were not identified, the answers to these and other questions

were impossible to obtain.  (See, Transcript, vol. IV, pp.

817-830).

 

            The need for such information was made more crucial by

the fact that home ownership constituted a prime component of

the Report.  Mr. Schneider failed to convince the neutral arbi-

trator that the statistical processes used by Runzheimer

necessarily would have weeded out of the study any inappropri-

ate comparisons.  His conviction provided insufficient

assurance that conclusions drawn by the Report are completely

accurate.  (See, Transcript, vol. IV, pp. 819-820).

 

            As a result of such uncertainties, the Runzheimer Report

has been used only as another source of guidance; and the

arbitrator has not relied exclusively on the conclusions of

the Runzheimer Report as a precise measure of cost-of-living

differences between Seattle and the comparative cities.  At

the same time, the Report has not been discounted entirely.

As the evidence submitted by the parties made clear, the

Runzheimer Report was not the only evidence showing that the

cost of living in comparative cities is higher than it is in

Seattle.

 

            Data from the American Chamber of Commerce Researchers

Association showed that the cost-of-living in Seattle for

the second quarter of 1986 was 3.6% lower than that of com-

parative cities.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 80(B)).  Likewise,

data from the Associates for International Research, Inc.

indicated that, for a before tax income of $40,000, Seattle's

cost of living was 15.2% lower than that of San Francisco or

Los Angeles in 1986.  (See, City's Exhibit Nos. 1, 2 and 83;

Transcript, vol. III, p. 87).  Updated from 1981, the Bureau

of Labor Statistics' higher Urban Family Budget showed a 9.7%

differential in cost of living between Seattle and the com-

parative cities of San Francisco, Qakland, Long Beach, and

San Diego in 1986.  (See, City's Exhibit No. 75(E).  Based on

data from the American Chamber of Commerce Researchers'

Association, Coldwell Banker Residential Group, Inc., a 1980

Bureau of the Census report, and a report by the Federal Home

Loan Bank Board for the third quarter of 1986, there was an

indication that home costs in Seattle ranged from 17% to 48%

less to buy than in some of the comparative cities.  (See,

City's Exhibit Nos. 84, 85, and 86).  Additionally, there was

unrebutted evidence that the 1985-86 Consumer Price Index for

Seattle was .3% as contrasted with 2.1% in comparative cities

and that Seattle's Consumer Price Index had increased by 13.8

fewer points than the average in those other relevant west

coast cities from 1967 to 1985.  (See, City's Exhibit Nos.

70, 71, and 72).  While these data were of varying degrees

of usefulness and reliability, they served as an indicator

that costs of living in comparative cities are higher than in

Seattle.

 

            The Knowles Theory.     Through the testimony of Professor

David Knowles, Associate Professor at Seattle University, the

Association advanced a different theory with respect to how

the cost of living should be measured.  The Association argued

that a higher cost of living escalates wages, making inter-

city wage differences a proxy for inter-city cost-of-living

differences.  If costs of living are higher in the comparative

cities than in Seattle, the Association maintained that

cross-industry area wage surveys should reveal the fact that

workers in the comparative cities received more compensation

than do their counterparts in Seattle.  (See, Transcript,

vol. VI, pp. 1332-1333).

 

            The Association argued, however, that the facts did

not reveal such wage differences.  When the Bureau of Labor

Statistics issued weekly earnings across industries from

July, 1986, Seattle employes received no less compensation

than workers in comparative cities.  (See, Association's

Exhibit Nos. 196 and 197; Transcript, vol. VI, pp. 1337-1341).

City government payroll data from the Bureau of Labor Statis-

tics from 1984 showed that city employes in comparative

cities received only 1.3% more compensation than did their

Seattle counterparts during the relevant time period.  (See,

Association's Exhibit No. 198).  Moreover, the per capita

money income in the comparative cities, on the average, was

10.4% less than that in Seattle.  (See, Association's Exhibit

No. 109).  Accordingly, the Association has argued that

Seattle is at least as expensive a city in which to live as

any of the comparative locations.

 

            These data, however, failed to be persuasive.  Occupa-

tions Dr. Knowles chose to study from the BLS area wage

surveys did not constitute a true cross-section of wage

earners but, rather, focused on clerical, technical, or

mechanical professions.  Thus, it is possible that the wage

figure averages on which Dr. Knowles based his comparisons

were skewed.  The point is that the Association failed to

establish the relevance of such salaries to compensation paid

management personnel, except as a general economic force

confronting the parties.

 

            The city government payroll data relied on by the Asso-

ciation were somewhat dated (October, 1984)   and failed to

take into account the differences in services offered by the

various cities.  (See, Transcript, vol. VI, p. 1422).  Finally,

per capita money income comparisons may take into account

income unrelated to wages without considering differences in

occupational structures within a particular city.  (See,

Transcript, vol. VI, pp. 1424-1425).  As a result, less confi-

dence has been placed in conclusions based on these data.

 

            The Association has argued that none of the indices of

inter-city cost-of-living differentials introduced into

evidence by the City may be relied on by the arbitration

panel.  According to the Association, each must be considered

unreliable because of flawed data collection practices, lack

of availability of underlying data, or because the City

failed to produce witnesses capable of providing an adequate

foundation for the studies.  It should be observed, however,

that independent and generally disinterested organizations

whose purpose is to analyze "cost-of-living" differences on

a national basis conducted many of the studies cited by the

Employer.  Each may be subject to criticism with respect to

methodology or data collection processes.  Even Bureau of

Labor Statistics studies, on which the Association relied for

its own cost-of-living analysis, are susceptible to the criti-

cism that the underlying data cannot be completely validated.

Yet, the arbitration panel has been unwilling to ignore

generally consistent conclusions reached in the variety of

independent studies.  To allow any flaw in a study to eliminate

its evidentiary usefulness would remove much helpful informa-

tion from the purview of the arbitration panel and also would

call into question the legitimate statutory criteria enacted

by the legislature.  As Arvid Anderson, president of the

National Academy of Arbitrators, has pointed out, "lawyers

are very skillful at raising objections as to the admissi-

bility or to the relevance of particular data, however, in

interest arbitration what is really important is the persua-

siveness and relevance of what is presented."  (See, Anderson,

"Public Sector Interest Arbitration Lessons from Recent

Experience," Address to the Society of Professionals  in

Dispute Resolution in Boston, Massachusetts, October, 1985).

 

            On the other hand, the arbitrator has not relied on

the studies in a rigid or literalistic way as a means of

demonstrating a mathematically precise differential in costs

of living between Seattle and the comparative cities.  The

differing conclusions in the studies cited by the parties

amply demonstrate that "cost-of-living" analysis is at best

an imprecise science.  Such data simply cannot be used as

an inflexible formula to compute wage parity in "real" dol-

lars as the Employer has suggested.  Rather, the sum total

of the information has served to inform the arbitration

panel that the cost of living in comparative cities is,

within a general range, higher in comparative locations than

in Seattle, Washington.  Accordingly, it is reasonable for

the arbitration panel to conclude that wage disparities

between Seattle and the comparative cities, on the one hand,

are not so great as some have argued, nor, on the other hand,

insignificant.

 

            A Wage Increase of Four Percent:   The "cost-of-

living" factor,  then, is only one of several factors set

forth in the legislation.  It is the task of the arbitration

panel to evaluate conclusions that should be drawn from an

amalgamation of these criteria and to make a wage determina-

tion that is reasonable within the context of these statutory

factors.  A salary increase of 4% comes as close as possible

to fulfilling this goal.  Pursuant to this increase, the base

monthly salaries of police lieutenants, captains, and majors

would be $3,828.00, $4,402.00, and $5,062.00, respectively.

 

            An effort has been made to illustrate the impact of this

increase.  In terms of base monthly salary, Seattle police

personnel would rank as follows among the stipulated compara-

tive cities:

 

 

Lieutenants

            Cities                                      Wage

            San Jose                                 $4,176.00

            Long Beach                            $4,173.00

            Oakland                                  $3,981 .00

            San Francisco             $3,976.00

            Seattle                                                $3,828.00

            San Diego                               $3,734.00

            Portland                                  $3,724.00

            Sacramento                            $3,398.00

                                                            ($4,123.00 with education incen-

                                                            tive pay)

 

Captains

            San Jose                                 $4,835.00

            Sacramento                            $4,726.00

            Long Beach                            $4,696.00

            San Francisco             $4,668.00

            Oakland                                  $4,602.00

            Seattle                                                $4,402.00

            Portland                                  $4,280.00

            San Diego                               $4,209.00

 

Majors

            Oakland                                  $5,719.00

            San Jose                                 $5,613.00

            San Francisco             $5,516.00

            Seattle                                                $5,062.00

            Portland                                  $4,905.00

 

 

            A wage increase of 4% would place Seattle police lieu-

tenants 2% below the average base monthly wage of $3,906.00

in California cities (5.2% below, if Sacramento's education

incentive pay is included in the calculation) .  In comparison

with all of the comparative cities, Seattle lieutenants will

receive 1.4% less compensation than the average of $3,880.00

(or 4.5% less if Sacramento's education longevity is included).

They will receive 2.8% more compensation in base monthly

wages than portland lieutenants.

 

            Seattle captains will receive 5% less in base monthly

wages compared with the stipulated California cities.  They

will receive 3.9% below the average base monthly wage of

$4,574.00 for all the comparative cities.  Not all the com-

parative cities employ majors whose rank is comparable to

that of a "major " in Seattle.  (See, Transcript, vol. I,

pp. 153 and 163).  The data for those which do so indicate

that Seattle majors will earn 7.5% less compensation than

majors in comparative cities with an actual dollar differen-

tial of $381 .00.

 

            An effort also has been made to compare the impact on

total   hourly   compensation of a 4% wage increase, using

the same method of computation as previously described

earlier in the report with respect to total hourly compensation.

This information has been especially useful because it accounts

for differences in types of pay received by police management

personnell such as education incentive or holiday pay.  The

data show the following pattern:

 

 

Cities                                      Lieutenants

Long Beach                            $29.13

San Jose                                 $28.62

Oakland                                  $27.09

Sacramento                            $26.97

Seattle                                                $25.37

Portland                                  $25.21

San Diego                               $25.12

San Francisco             $25.01

 

 

 Cities                                     Captains

San Jose                                 $32.94

Long Beach                           $ 32.53

Oakland                                 $ 30.89

Sacramento                            $30.11

San Francisco             $29.26

Seattle                                                $28.91

Portland                                  $28.39

San Diego                               $28.17

 

 

Cities                                      Majors

San Jose                                 $37.99

Oakland                                  $37.72

San Francisco             $34.47

Portland                                  $33.13

Seattle                                                $32.97

           

 

 

            These data show that, with a wage increase of 4%,

Seattle police lieutenants will receive 6.4% less than the

average hourly wage of $26.99 among comparative cities in

California.  When Portland is included, Seattle will receive

5.4% less than the average hourly wage.  Seattle lieutenants

will receive .6% more total compensation per hour than

Portland lieutenants.

 

            Seattle captains will receive 6.0% less than the average

hourly compensation received by captains in California cities

and 5.2% less than that received by captains in all the com-

parative cities.  Seattle majors will receive 8.7% less than

the average received by majors in other comparative cities.

 

            These data make clear that members of this bargaining

unit will receive less actual compensation than the average

received in other west coast cities with which Seattle has

been compared, although the actual dollar differentials are

not overwhelming.  For a number of reasons, the arbitration

panel believes Seattle's rank order among the comparative

cities reflects a reasonable way of balancing the statutory

criteria.  First, as the data have made clear, there is an

overall higher cost of living to be found in comparative

cities than there is in Seattle.  Depending on the study used

as the basis of one's conclusion, the differential can range

from 3.1% to 9.7%.  (See, City's Exhibit Nos. 70, 72, 80-86,

and 130-131 ).

 

            Another point to highlight is the fact that the data

consistently show averages of salaries among the comparative

cities to be higher when portland has been excluded from the

consideration.  Thus, while concededly based on comparisons

of wages received by police management personnel in the

stipulated cities, even the Association 's  "wage proxy"

method of measuring cost of living would suggest that California

cities experience a higher cost of living than do the two

largest cities in the pacific Northwest.  This assumption has

been supported by data from the Association showing that, among

the comparison cities between 1976 and 1986, only portland had

a lower CPI than did Seattle.  (See, Association's Exhibit

No. 17).  For this reason, portland salary data in this case

have been of more than casual interest.  A 4% salary increase

would place the salaries of Seattle lieutenants and captains

above those similarly situated employes in portland.

 

            It is also important to recognize the impact of a 4% wage

increase on the place of Seattle police lieutenants in the

local labor market,a factor which must be given its due weight.

Within that context, salaries received by members of the bar-

gaining unit will be high, but not unreasonably so.  Compared

with the average base monthly salaries of police lieutenants

in the Tacoma, Renton, Bellvue, Mercer Island, Auburn, Everett,

and Kent, Seattle lieutenants will receive 10.3% more compensation

(9.4%, when Tacoma's longevity pay is included as part of a

Tacoma lieutenant's base monthly pay).  Seattle captains will

receive 16.3% more compensation than the average of their counter-

parts in Auburn, Bellvue, Everett, Lynwod, Kent, Edmonds, and Tacoma.

 

            Nor can the impact on the internal wage structure be

ignored.  As will be recalled, Seattle police lieutenants

have been paid an average of 26% more compensation than the

License and Standards Supervisor for the last twenty years.

A 4% raise will increase this differential to 30.6%.  Lieu-

tenants will receive 7.5% more compensation than Electrical

Worker supervisors, which is slightly below the twenty year

average of 8.3%.

 

            There also is a need for the arbitration panel to be

sensitive to the Employer's need to maintain sensible differ-

entials between ranks within the department.  A 4% wage

increase will give members of this bargaining unit an equi-

table wage without distorting internal differentials.  Police

lieutenants will receive 23.3% more compensation in base

monthly wages than will police sergeants.  (See, City's

Exhibit No. 145).  If maximum longevity is included in the

calculation for a sergeant's pay, the differential will be

only 15.3%.  Assuming the Assistant Chief of Police received

a .5% wage increase, this individual would be paid only 3.7%

more compensation than a police major.  As previously suggested,

however, this issue cannot be dispositive.  With respect to

the Chief and Assistant Chief of Police, the Employer has the

power to structure the salary differentials as it deems it

prudent.

 

            The Association has raised a number of arguments to sup-

port a much higher wage increase that have not been persuasive.

For example, the Association has argued that, since 1979,

historical data show a steady erosion in the relative economic

position of wages in this bargaining unit as compared with

the stipulated cities.  That is, among the comparisons, Seattle

was the wage leader in 1979 but gradually lost ground until,

in 1986, it ranked almost last.  (See, Association's Exhibit

No. 14).  It is a forceful argument when a bargaining unit

can clearly demonstrate that it has been a wage leader over

a period of years.  Because a city's reputation as a wage

leader may attract the highest quality personnel, its status

in this respect benefits not only bargaining unit members but

also the Employer and the public as well.  The Association,

however, has not explicitly shown such a history as a wage

leader with respect to Seattle.  On the contrary, data show

that Seattle's wage leadership has varied erratically over

the past twenty years.  The data reveal the following pattern:

 

            Cities                                      1966-67

            San Francisco             $1,029.00

            San Diego                               $1,027.00

            Long Beach                            $999.00

            San Jose                                 $968.00

            Oakland                                  $950.00

            Sacramento                            $900.00

            Portland                                  $877.00

            Seattle                                                $810.00

 

 

 

            Cities                                      1975-76

            Long Beach                            $2,131.00

            Oakland                                  $2,110.00

            San Francisco             $2,082.00

            San Jose                                 $2,051.00

            Seattle                                                $2,023.00

            Portland                                  $1,992.00

            Sacramento                            $1 ,859.00

            San Diego                               $1 ,823.00

 

 

            Cities                                      1978-79

            Seattle                                                $2,610.00

            Oakland                                  $2,496.00

            Portland                                  $2,439.00

            San Francisco             $2,427.00

            Long Beach                            $2,332.00

            San Jose                                 $2,267.00

            Sacramento                            $2,259.00

            San Diego                               $2,186.00

 

 

            Cities                                      1981-82

            Long Beach                            $3,188.00

            Seattle                                                $3,166.00

            San Jose                                 $3,045.00

            Oakland                                  $3,004.00

            San Francisco             $2,995.00

            Portland                                  $2,917.00

            Sacramento                            $2,734.00

            San Diego                               $2,572.00

 

 

            Cities                                      1985-86

            San Jose                                 $4,010.00

            Long Beach                            $3,958.00

            Oakland                                  $3,792.00

            San Francisco             $3,758.00

            Seattle                                                $3,681.00

            Portland                                  $3,604.00

            San Diego                               $3,426.00

            Sacramento                            $3,268.00

 

 

The data simply do not support a conclusion that Seattle has

been a consistent wage leader among west coast cities with

respect to base monthly salaries for police lieutenants.  The

fact that Seattle ranked first in 1979 has not established

the city as a wage leader with respect to police management

personnel.  The point is, of course, that comparability data

cannot play as important a role in wage determinations for a

wage leader, although it is presumed to be significant.

 

            The Association has also argued that the Employer has the

ability to pay members of the bargaining unit as much as a 30% in-

crease.  The City has not contested its ability to pay, and

evidence submitted to the arbitration panel shows that the

economic tenor of the Employer has improved since the early

1980s.  Those improved conditions clearly warrant a 4% wage

increase.  Members of this bargaining unit, like other employes,

should expect to share in the City's economic recovery.

 

            On the other hand, the objective of an interest arbitra-

tion is not to determine the extreme limits of what an employer

might be able to afford, but rather to determine an equitable

and fair wage rate based on objective data.  The City was

persuasive in its contention that the Association's proposed

total compensation package is too costly.  According to the

City's calculations and assuming a 10% per year wage increase,

the Association's complete proposal over the next three years

would provide each bargaining unit member with $52,534.00

more than he or she currently receives.  At the end of the

three years, members of this bargaining unit would have re-

ceived about twice as much in additional compensation as the

City currently expends for those individuals in one year.

(See, City's Exhibit No. 156).  Consequently a number of

interests must be balanced in making this wage determination,

among them enabling the Employer to maintain its economic

recovery, making progress on other priorities, and remaining

cautious during a time of unpredictable economic forces.

 

            Nor have the City's arguments in support of a 1.5% wage

increase been persuasive.  The City has argued that, within

the context of the local labor market, members of this bar-

gaining unit are already extremely well paid.  According to

the Employer, salary increases among local public agencies

averaged approximately 2% in 1986 and 1987.  The Seattle

Police Officers Guild negotiated a 1.5% salary increase,

effective September 1, 1986.  (See, Transcript, vol. V,

p. 1167).  Local 17 of the Joint Crafts Council and the Inter-

national Federation of Professional and Technical Engineers

negotiated a first year wage increase averaging approximately

1%, with increases based on the Seattle area CPI-W in the

second and third years.  (See, Transcript, vol. V, pp. 1175-78).

 

            The arbitration panel recognizes that there is a differen-

tial that favors police personnel when they are compared

with certain other City supervisors.  In addition to the

historic pattern, some weight also must be given to the fact

that services performed by police managers are both indispen-

sable and unusually hazardous.  To the extent that their

salaries exceed those received by some other city supervisors

and managers, the higher pay simply recognizes the special

nature of the work performed by members of the bargaining

unit.

 

            Later Years of the Agreement:   Ideally, the comparable

salary levels achieved by members of the bargaining unit in

1986 should be preserved in the second and third years of the

parties  collective bargaining agreement.  The Association

has submitted data with respect to 1987 negotiated settle-

ment with police management personnel in six of the seven

stipulated cities.  According to the affidavit of Mr. Gerald

Taylor, immediate past president of the Association, total

compensation increases among comparative cities of San Jose,

Long Beach, Oakland, San Francisco, San Diego, and Sacramento

have averaged 5.4%.  Salary increases among the same cities

have averaged 4.8%.  (See, Association's post-hearing Brief,

p. 19).

 

            The arbitrators have received no data with respect to

the increase in total compensation received by Portland

police management personnel.  Portland, however, appears to

have received a salary increase of 2% in 1986-87.  (See,

Association's Exhibit No. 20, fn. 2).  When Portland's increase

is included in the computation, the average salary increase

among all the stipulated cities is 4.4%   Accordingly, it is

reasonable to award members of the bargaining unit a second

year salary increase of 4.4%, with an aim of maintaining

their close to average position among the stipulated cities.

 

            Obviously, there has been no similar information avail-

able for the contract year beginning September 1, 1988.  In

light of the fact that those agreements are yet to be nego-

tiated, the City's proposal to link the third year salary

increase to the CPI index is a rational one.  This method of

wage determination insures that members of the bargaining

unit will not lose ground as a result of inflation.  Addi-

tionally, by providing a "floor  and a "ceiling," neither

party will suffer greatly from an unpredictably low or high

rate of inflation from January to June of 1988.

 

            The City's salary proposal for the third year of the

parties' agreement, however, should be modified in two

respects.  First, the City has proposed that the third year

wage increase should equal 80% of the Seattle-Tacoma area

CPI-W.  The Employer, however, has conceded that in its

settlements with the Joint Crafts Council and International

Federation of Professional and Technical Engineers, Local 17,

it has agreed to increase wages by 90% of the Seattle area

CPI-W in subsequent contract years.  (See, Transcript, vol.

V, p. 1176).  Additionally, the parties used the 90% CPI-W

formula in their expired agreement.  (See, Association's

Exhibit No. 4, App. A).  In consideration of the parties'

past agreement, settlements with other unions, and the objec-

tive of tying wages of this bargaining unit to a percentage

of the CPI, 90% is the more appropriate figure to use.

 

 

            A second change in the Employer's proposed third year

wage increase focuses on the index to be used.  Professor

Knowles  presented unrebutted testimony that the Bureau of

Labor Statistics now discourages using local indices in labor

settlements because their frequency and reliability have

decreased in recent years.  (See, Transcript, vol. 6, pp.

1369-1371).  Consequently, it is currently more appropriate

to link the third year wage increase to the Consumer Price

Index for Urban Wage Earners and Clerical Workers.  The CPI-W

is an older index than the CPI-U, and the CPI-W has histori-

cal roots that link it to the index which was initiated during

World War I for use in wage negotiations.  Hence, it is

reasonable to use the CPI-W for all cities.

 

 

VI.       THE ISSUE OF SPECIALTY PAY

 

A.        Proposal:

 

            The Association has proposed that the basic monthly

salary of a police lieutenant assigned to the Bomb Squad be

increased by 5%.

 

 

 

B.        Discussion:

 

            The current practice is for police lieutenants on

assignment to the Bomb Squad to receive 5% of the "top step"

police officer's salary.  (See, Transcript, vol. I, p. 190).

Yet, detectives and sergeants, who are members of the Seattle

Police Officers Guild, receive 8% of a "top step" police

officer's salary.  (See, Association's Exhibit No. 40).

Obviously, the current structure pays police lieutenants, who

are members of the Seattle Police Management Association,

less compensation for serving on the Bomb Squad than is paid

to individuals who rank below lieutenants.

 

            The Employer would continue this disparity.  It is the

position of the Employer that the wage disparity is justified

by the bargaining history of the "specialty pay"  provision.

 

The provision states:

 

Effective September 1 , 1983 , a salary premium based

on five percent (5%) of the top base pay step of

the classification Police Officer shall be paid to

Police Lieutenant assigned to the Bomb Squad while

so assigned.  The dollar equivalent to this percen-

tage premium is $122.00 per month, effective September

1, 1983, and $129.00 per month effective September 1,

1984.  (See, Association's Exhibit No. 4, p. 29).

 

 

In other words, in originally negotiating Bomb Squad pay with

the Seattle Police Officers Guild, the Employer wanted to pay

those individuals covered by the provision a "flat dollar"

amount.  The Seattle Police Officers Guild, on the other

hand, wanted to link the wage rate to a percentage of the

individuals' salary, thus allowing Bomb Squad pay to advance

as general wages increased.  (See, Transcript, vol. V,

pp. 1190-1191).  This obviously is an instance where shadows

of the past are distorting present day reality.  The rationale

set forth by the Employer is not given any force through the

Employer's current practice of paying police lieutenants less

than detectives and sergeants for undergoing the same hazard

and using the same skills.  Current practice also has the

potential to undermine the morale of middle level decision

makers.

 

            A more rational approach is to be found in the Associa-

tion's proposal.  The cost of the proposal is not great. More

importantly, the inequity of paying lieutenants less than

officers of lower rank for exercising the same basic skills

will be removed by implementing the Association's proposal.

Moreover, adopting the Association's proposal will recognize

the special role and increased decision making responsibility

borne by management personnel assigned to perform Bomb Squad

duty.

 

 

 

VII.     THE ISSUE OF CAREER DEVELOPMENT INCENTIVES

 

A.        Proposal:

 

            The Association has proposed that two contractual provi-

sions which focus on career development be included in the

parties' agreement.  First, the Association seeks educational-

longevity pay for members of the bargaining unit.  Pursuant

to this proposal, a member of the bargaining unit with one year

of college education or five years of service will receive

an additional 2.5% in base monthly salary.  If that indivi-

dual had obtained two years of college education or ten

years of work experience, he or she would receive an additional

5% of compensation.  With three years of education or fifteen

years of service, he or she would receive an additional 10% of

salary.  With an MA or MS degree, 11% in salary would be

added.  If the individual had earned a Ph.D. or J.D. degree,

he or she would receive 12% more monthly pay.  The proposal

would permit members of the bargaining unit to compound full

increments of educational training with years of service to

obtain a maximum of 10% of career development pay.  Under the

plan, longevity pay eventually would cease to exist.

 

            Second, the Association has proposed a plan of tuition

reimbursement for pre-approved college courses.  Under this

plan, members of the bargaining unit who received a grade of

"A" would be paid the lesser of 100% of the cost or $300.00.

For a grade of "B," the individual would receive the lesser

of 75% of the cost, or $225.00; and for a grade of "C," he

or she would receive the lesser of 50% of the cost or $150.00.

 

 

Bargaining unit members would be permitted to take as many

as two courses at any one time, and the plan would apply to

course work completed on or after January 1 , 1987.

 

B.        Discussion:

 

            A fundamental justification for the Association's pro-

posal is that highly educated police management personnel are

a central part of a top quality, highly professional city

police department.  It is the belief of the Association that

providing additional pay for increased levels of college edu-

cation would create an effective incentive for members of the

bargaining unit to seek further college training.  Such a

plan also would reward those individuals who already have

attained higher levels of education through their own efforts.

Furthermore, the Association has maintained that its proposal

will encourage police officers who aspire to managerial

positions to seek additional education.

 

            The arbitrator has no doubt that education plays an

important role in establishing and maintaining a professional

police department.  This is as true for managerial personnel

as it is for an officer  "on the street."  The American Bar

Association project on standards for criminal justice has

recognized the need to attract to police work and police

administration individuals with a broad liberal education.

One observer has stated:

 

 

            The qualities which law enforcement leaders claim

            to look for in  recruits are the very ones

which liberal education is believed to nurture:

knowledge of changing social, economic and political

conditions; understanding of human behavior; and

the ability to communicate; together with the assump-

tion of certain moral values, habits of mind, and

qualities of self-discipline which are important

in sustaining their commitment to public service.

(See, Association's Exhibit No. 57, p. 218).

 

            At the same time that more education is desirable within

the work force, the most effective means for attracting quali-

fied individuals well might be paying a salary that adequately

reflects the higher educational training expected of such

individuals.  This is a more direct and efficient means of

achieving the Association's goal for its members.  The

Employer submitted evidence showing that most members of this

particular bargaining unit already have achieved a solid

education.  (See, City's Exhibit Nos. 174, 175, and 176).

Additionally, because the Employer has tended to encourage

internal promotions, most members of the bargaining unit have

served a great many years with the department.  Consequently,

career incentive pay would serve not so much as an incentive to

obtain more education as it would serve as a reward for past

efforts.  This objective is better accomplished by paying

members of the bargaining unit higher compensation in recog-

nition of their status as highly educated, experienced mem-

bers of the department.

 

            It also must be recalled that 52% of all sergeants in

the department applied for the position of "police lieutenant"

in the last qualifying examination.  (See, City's Exhibit No.181).

 

 

 

The point is that police sergeants clearly have a view of

being promoted to a managerial position as a desirable goal.

It is reasonable to believe that this partly is because man-

agerial positions are relatively well paid.  To the extent

that a higher degree of education increases their chance to

be assigned to such a position, police officers already have

a strong incentive for obtaining further education.

 

            The Association has argued that four of the seven compara-

tive cities have established some form of educational and/or

longevity pay for police managerial employes.  (See, Associa-

tion's Exhibit No. 3).  Fairness requires, however, that this

"additional" contractual benefit be evaluated in relationship

to the total compensation package received by police managers

in those cities.  For example, Sacramento restricts educa-

tional pay for police managers to the position of "lieuten-

ants," an apparent compensation for giving them the lowest

monthly salary of any of the stipulated West Coast cities.

(See, Transcript, vol.11, p. 155).  To the extent that Seattle

police managerial personnel are provided comparable total

compensation, the fact that other cities provide educational

and/or longevity pay becomes less convincing as a basis for

including it in this agreement.

 

            Nor can one lose sight of the enormous expense to the

Employer of the Association's career development incentive

proposal.  At current salary rates, the minimum additional

salary to be received by each bargaining unit member would

be $5000.00.  (See, Transcript, vol. V, p. 1092).  Over a

three year period, the Association's proposal could cost the

Employer approximately a million dollars.  (See, City's

Exhibit 158).  In balancing the interests of the parties and

the gains to be obtained by the Association's proposal, it is

reasonable to conclude that the cost simply is too great at

this time.

 

            Much the same rationale militates against accepting the

Association's tuition reimbursement proposal.  The Association

was persuasive in its contention that training programs

currently paid for by the Employer do not provide educational

benefits equivalent to those attained through college course

work.  The fact remains, however, that most members of this

bargaining unit already have obtained a considerable amount

of college education.

 

            The Association has argued that many members of the

bargaining unit have financed their education through the

federal Law Enforcement Education Program, a program that no

longer exists.  (See, Transcript, vol. II, p. 324).  As a

result, an alternative means for financing educational pro-

grams of bargaining unit members is needed, according to

the Association.  Direct wage payments, however, are the most

efficient means of enabling bargaining unit members to advance

their education and this does not become encumbered with additional

bureaucratic overlays inherent in implementing the Association's

proposal.  The worthwhile objective of providing the addi-

tional benefit does not merit the costs that would be generated

were the proposal adopted.  The Employer's estimated cost of

the proposal is over $60,000.00.  (See, City's Exhibit No.

160).

 

            In summary, the Association's proposals with respect to

career development incentives have not been included as a

part of the next agreement between the parties.  It is impor-

tant to emphasize, however, that the rationale for not doing

so has rested on the assumption that members of the bargaining

unit receive total compensation reasonably comparable to that

of relevant personnel in comparative cities.  This fact has

provided an additional reason for not adopting the City's

modest wage proposal.  By paying members of the bargaining

unit total compensation appropriate to their level of experi-

ence and education, they will be rewarded for their past

educational accomplishments.  More importantly, the police

department will continue to attract a highly educated, pro-

fessional managerial staff and will do so without incurring

the burdensome administrative costs entailed by the Associa-

tion's proposal.

 

 

VIII.    THE ISSUE OF DISCIPLINE

 

A.        Proposal:

 

            The Association has submitted a two-part proposal with

respect to discipline.  First, the Association proposes that

a "just cause"  provision be added to the collective bargaining

agreement between the parties.  Second, the Association

proposes that either the present disciplinary procedure be

incorporated into the parties' agreement or that any discip-

linary procedure negotiated between the Employer and the

Seattle Police Officers Guild be incorporated into the agree-

ment with the Seattle Police Management Association, provided

that if those two parties resolve the issue in interest

arbitration, the Association be permitted to appear and

participate in the proceeding.

 

 

 

B.        Discussion:

 

                        In response to the Association's proposal, the Employer

has argued that disciplinary procedures currently used in the

Seattle Police Department are adequate and respond to the

needs of the parties.  It is the contention of the Employer

that lieutenants and captains in the department already enjoy

several sources of protection from unjust discipline.  For

example, lieutenants and captains may use the Manual of

Rules and procedures of the Seattle Police Department.  In

addition, these personnel have access to the Public Safety

Civil Service Commission pursuant to the Rules of Practice

and Procedure of the Commission.  Additionally, they may

appeal to a local Superior Court.  It is the contention of

the Employer that such procedures more than adequately protect

the needs of lieutenants and captains.

 

            With respect to majors, the City has acknowledged that

City Ordinance 4.08.060 covers not only lieutenants and

captains but excludes majors from its jurisdiction.  Majors

in the department serve at the behest of the Chief of Police.

That is appropriate, according to the Employer, because majors

are top level managers on whom the chief relies in determining

and carrying out important policy objectives.  The City has

argued that, without the total confidence of the chief of

police, majors would be unable to serve effectively in this

position.  Consequently, the City has argued that the chief

must be permitted absolute, unilateral discretion to choose

and, if necessary to replace majors whom he believes to be

incompatible with his goals.  To the extent that a "just

cause" provision would alter this arrangement, it allegedly

would be consistent with the best interests of the parties.

 

 

 

            Placing "Just Cause" in Context.     It is not unusual

for public sector administrators to view  grievance

procedures as disruptive.  (See, Patterson, The Public Admin-

istrator's Grievance Arbitration   Handbook, p. 4 (1983)).  It

also is not unusual for management to urge employes to rely

on protections made available through civil service commis-

sions.  But public sector collective bargaining has added a

dimension that has begun altering traditional attitudes.  As

one author observed almost a decade ago,  the existence and

growth of collective bargaining is circumscribing the tradi-

tional role of civil service commissions as the personnel

arms of government."  (See, Reeves, Collective Bargaining in

the Public Sector, p. 38 (1978)).

 

            There are at least two primary reasons for adopting some

sort of grievance procedure as a part of the collective

bargaining relationship between the parties.  First, a griev-

ance procedure represents more than just another article in

a negotiated agreement.  It represents a statement about the

parties' understanding of their relationship.  A somewhat

lengthy statement by the U.S. Supreme Court explains the

primacy of a grievance procedure in a collective bargaining

relationship.  The Court has stated:

 

A collective bargaining agreement is an effort to

erect a system of industrial self-government. When

most parties enter into professional relationships

they do so voluntarily, in the sense that there is

no real compulsion to deal with one another, as

opposed to dealing with other parties.  This is

not true of the labor agreement.  The choice is

generally not between entering or refusing to enter

into a relationship, for that in all probability

preexists the negotiations.  Rather, it is between

having that relationship governed by an agreed upon

rule of law or leaving each and every matter sub-

ject to a temporary resolution dependent solely

upon the relevant strength, at any given moment,

of the contending forces.  The mature labor agree-

ment may attempt to regulate all aspects of the

complicated relationship, from the most crucial

to the most minute over an extended period of time.

Because of the compulsion to reach agreement and

the breadth of the matters covered, as well as the

need for a fairly concise and readable instrument,

the product of negotiations [the written document]

is, in the words of the late Dean Shulman, 'a compi-

lation of diverse provisions:  some provide objec-

tive criteria almost automatically applicable;

some provide more or less specific standards which

require reason and judgment in their application;

and some do little more than leave problems to

future consideration with an expression of hope

and good faith.'  Gaps may be left to be filled in

by reference to the practices of the particular

industry and of the various shops covered by the

agreement.  Many of the specific practices which

underlie the agreement may be unknown, except in

hazy form, even to the negotiators.  Courts and

arbitration in the context of most commercial con-

tracts are resorted to because there has been a

breakdown in the working relationship of the par-

ties; such resort is the unwanted exception.  But

the grievance machinery under a collective bargain-

ing agreement is at the very heart of the system

of industrial self-government.  Arbitration is the

means of solving the unforeseeable by molding a

system of private law for all of the problems

which may arise and to provide for their solution

in a way which will generally accord with the

variant needs and desires of the parties.  The pro-

cessing of disputes through the grievance machinery

is actually a vehicle by which meaning and content

are given to the collective bargaining agreement.

(See, United Steelworkers of America v. Warrior and

            Gulf Navigation Company, 363 U.S. 574 (1960)).

 

 

            The point is that a grievance procedure, including the

concept of just cause, is a part of a system of self-government.

The objective of the system is not only to secure justice for

those covered by the agreement but also to assist an employer

in its quest for productivity and efficiency.  If a grievance

arbitrator is asked to assist in the relationship of the

parties, it is his or her obligation to recognize the continu-

ing nature of the relationship between the parties.  Within

the context of that continuing relationship, he or she, then,

attempts, based strictly on objective evidence submitted by

the parties, to determine their contractual intent and to

implement it.

 

            A second reason for adopting a traditional grievance

procedure as part of the parties' agreement involves the

concept of just cause.  This is not a mystifying or elusive

concept, even though no standardized definition can be applied

like a mathematical formula to all problems.  The concept of

"just cause" has brought to the work place fundamental

notions of due process that have provided the basis for the

foundation and growth of justice in the United States. "Just

cause"  assumes that there will be a reasonable basis for a

managerial decision to impose discipline  at the time of the

discipline.  Thus, an employer will not be permitted to

discipline based on arbitrary, capricious, or discriminatory

considerations.  "Just cause"  would be violated if management

searched for just cause reasons for an action after making

the decision.  It is assumed that just cause will be based

on a valid type of employe failure and not merely on indivi-

dual preferences or predilections.  "Just cause"  uses a

carefully defined concept which has been explored and explained

by literally hundreds of arbitration decisions during the

past forty-five years.  (See, for example, criteria used by

Arbitrator Daugherty in Grief Brothers, (42 LA 555 (1964)).

 

            An integral part of the concept of "just cause" is that

of due process.  One of the ironies of civil law is that it

has not developed protections in the work place that are as

effective as those of the concept of "just cause."  This is

best exemplified by the facts in the Bishop v. Wood case.  In

that case, management had discharged a police officer after the

chief of police concluded that his work was unsatisfactory.

Believing his employment status was a property right which

had been violated without regard for his due process rights,

the police officer challenged the decision.  In the view of

the U.S. Supreme Court, however, any due process rights the

individual enjoyed would not give him a guarantee against

incorrect or ill-advised personnel actions.  (See, Government

Employment Relations Reporter, 661:F-1, June 14, 1976).  More

recently, the U.S. Supreme Court has held that a public employe

may not be deprived of his or her substantive rights to

property except pursuant to constitutionally adequate pro-

cedures.  (See, Cleveland Board of Education v. Loudermill,

105 5. Ct. 1487 (1985)).  What the Court held, however, was

that the due process clauses of the fifth and fourteenth

amendments require  "some kind of hearing" prior to discharge.

(See, 105 S. Ct. 1487, 1493 (1985)).

 

            It still is not clear what requirements of procedural

due process public employes enjoy if the managerial action

does not involve discharge.  It also must be understood that

the U.S. Supreme Court never has clearly defined what con-

stitutes procedural due process.  Rather, the Court has stated

that "the exact boundaries [of due process] are indefinable,

and its content varies according to specific factual contexts."

(See, Hannah v. Larche, 363 U.S. 420 (1960)).  The U.S.

Supreme Court has taught us that "a fundamental requirement

of due process is the opportunity to be heard."  (See, Arnett

v. Kennedy, 416 U.S. 134 , 178  (1974)).

 

            Arbitration law much more carefully and definitively has

developed the notion of due process as a part of the concept

of "just cause. "  Numerous cases have dealt with concepts

such as an employe's foreknowledge of the work rules; the

relationship of the work rule to the safe, efficient, and

orderly operation of an agency; the adequacy of any investi-

gation into an incident; the sufficiency of the evidence

against an employe; whether or not the decision was free of

arbitrariness and discrimination; and the relationship of the

discipline imposed to the seriousness of the offense.  There

are numerous arbitration cases and secondary treatises on the

subject.  (See, for example, Elkouri and Elkouri, How

Arbitration Works, (1985); and Fairweather, Practice and

Procedure in Labor Arbitration (1983)).

 

            The point is that protections set forth by the City's

alternative procedures are not equivalent to those provided

by a "just cause" provision.  For example, what standard of

proof would be required of the Employer in proving a lieutenant

or captain guilty of misconduct under its proposal?

 

There are well developed guidelines in arbitration law that

have been  defined  over the years.  "Just cause" provisions

are not unusual.  A survey by the Bureau of National Affairs,

Inc., of four hundred  collective  bargaining  agree-

ments showed "just cause" provisions in ninety-eight percent

of them.  (See, Basic Patterns in Union Contracts,  p. 6

(BA Books, 1983).

 

            It is unreasonable to expect to be able to answer a

major who had been demoted on potentially erroneous grounds

that managerial discretion requires such flexibility and unfettered

control.   The demands of equity must be answered in par-

ticular cases.  Nor does the fact that in the past members of

this bargaining unit have accepted a contractual provision

allowing such a result have persuasive power.  If there is a

dispute involving a clearcut managerial right and the evi-

dence is ambiguous, perhaps the benefit of the doubt would

favor the Employer.  But in matters of discipline where there

has been ambiguity, there has been an inclination to favor a

grievant, as reflected by the fact that the burden of proof

in discipline cases has been on the employer.  In discipline

and discharge cases, the outcome often will dramatically

affect a person's livelihood, and there should be a scrupu-

lously fair opportunity to test the decision making process

that placed an individual in such a predicament.

 

            It should be recalled that the Association has indicated

its willingness to incorporate into a "just cause" provision

a number of limitations.  First, the Association accepts the

proposition that an employe who pursues the remedy of arbi-

tration must waive other methods of appeal.  Second, a major

who seeks a remedy for reassignment pursuant to the "just

cause" provision may do so only when the Employer has stated

that the reason for reassignment was the individual's miscon-

duct.  (See, Association's Post-hearing Brief, p. 54, fn. 17).

 

These modifications to a standard "just cause" provision

are directly responsive to concerns of the Employer with such

a provision.

 

            A second part of the Association's "discipline" proposal

is troublesome.  The Association would incorporate into the

parties' collective bargaining agreement present disciplinary

procedures or some procedure used by the Seattle Police

Officers Guild,  assuming certain conditions could be met.

The Employer has been convincing in its contention that

incorporating the discipline provisions of the Police Depart-

ment Manual into the parties' agreement would be undesirable.

For example, it would be exceedingly difficult to make neces-

sary changes in the procedures because of the impact on col-

lective bargaining negotiations.  In the absence of more

extensive testimony and a more detailed scrutiny of various

procedures, interest arbitration does not provide an effec-

tive forum for selecting an appropriate disciplinary procedure

for the parties.

 

            The fact remains that the Association has demonstrated

the existence of a genuine problem with respect to current

disciplinary procedures.  (See, Association's Exhibit No. 52

and Transcript, vol. II, pp. 231-233).  It is appropriate for

members of the bargaining unit to expect to participate in

whatever changes are made in the procedures.  Some appropriate

mechanism is needed for insuring such participation.

 

            A sensible solution to the problem is to establish a

joint labor-management committee whose function is to review

provisions of the disciplinary procedures that the Employer

believes to be outmoded so that the parties can fashion a

system that is directly responsive to their needs.  Such

committee would be in a position to make recommendations

for updating departmental procedures as necessary.  In this

way, members of the bargaining unit will have an opportunity

to point out what they perceive to be as inadequacies in any

proposed changes, and the Employer will be able to update and

streamline the Manual.

 

 

 

AWARD

 

 

            Having carefully considered all evidence submitted by

the parties concerning this matter and in accordance with

RCW 41.56.460, the arbitration panel in the impasse between

the City of Seattle and the Seattle Police Management

Association makes the following determinations:

 

1.         WAGES

 

            For the contract year beginning September 1, 1986,

members of the bargaining unit shall receive a 4% salary

increase.  Base monthly salaries for police lieutenants,

captains and majors shall be $3,828.00, $4,402.00, and

$5,062.00, respectively.

 

            For the contract year beginning September 1 , 1987,

members of the bargaining unit shall receive a salary

increase of 4.4%.

 

            For the contract year beginning September 1 , 1988,

members of the bargaining unit shall receive 90% of the

CPI-W (all cities), with a minimum wage increase of

3% and a maximum increase of 7%.

 

2.         CAREER DEVELOPMENT INCENTIVE

 

                        Neither the educational-longevity pay proposal

nor the tuition reimbursement proposal of the Association

shall be included as provisions in the next collective

bargaining agreement between the parties.

 

3.         SPECIALTY PAY

 

            The next collective bargaining agreement between

the parties shall provide that lieutenants assigned

to Bomb Squad duty shall receive an additional 5%

of their actual wage rate during the period of that

assignment.

 

 

4.         DISCIPLINE

 

            The next agreement between the parties shall

include a provision stating that it is a right of

management to suspend or discharge employes or take

other disciplinary action with just cause.  Addition-

ally, the parties shall establish a joint labor-

management committee with each party having equal

representation, and the charge to the committee shall

be to review and make recommendations with respect to

changes that should be made in the current Seattle

Police Department Manual, as it relates to the devel-

opment of a grievance procedure of a sort that is

responsive to the needs of the parties and the sort

customarily found in collective bargaining agreements.

It shall culminate with arbitration as the final step

of the procedure, using rules of the American Arbi-

tration Association.

 

 

            These determinations shall be implemented consistent

with the report issued in conjunction with this award.  The

arbitration panel shall retain jurisdiction in this matter

for thirty days from the date of the report in order to

resolve any problems resulting from its determination.

 

 

 

Respectfully submitted,

 

 

 

 

Lieutenant John Carson,

Association's party appointed

Panel Member

 

Date:____________________________

 

 

 

 

Ms. Carol Launch

City's party appointed Panel

Member

 

Date:_____________________________

 

 

 

 

Professor Carlton J. Snow

Neutral Panel Member and

Chairman of the Arbitration Panel

 

Date:_____________________________

 

 

 

 

IN THE MATTER OF INTEREST ARBITRATION

 

BETWEEN

 

SEATTLE POLICE MANAGEMENT ASSOCIATION

 

AND

 

CITY OF SEATTLE

 

(PERC No. 6502-1-86-148)

 

 

 

ASSOCIATION PARTISAN ARBITRATOR'S OPINION

 

 

 

 

            I regret that I am unable to sign the report of the

neutral chairman.  The report has a number of problems that

would not be productive to detail here.

 

 

            Most disappointingly, the report of the neutral chairman

provides no guidelines to assist the parties in settling their

next contract by negotiation, rather than by resort to time-

consuming, expensive, and divisive litigation.

 

 

            Interest arbitration decisions are most helpful to the

parties if they clearly set forth definitive guidelines in

terms likely to be persuasive to future arbitration panels, and

therefore, to the parties themselves.   Thus, for example,

guidelines articulated in arbitration reports issued in 1982

and 1983 enabled the Association and the City to stipulate to

the  appropriate  cities  for comparisons  pursuant  to  RCW

41.56.460(c).   Past reports also enabled the parties to

stipulate to much of the basic compensation data and to the

manner in which it should be developed and presented to the

panel.

 

            Regrettably, the report of the neutral chairman in this

case provides no such guidelines.  Instead, the report engages

primarily in the sort of non-quantitative balancing that

invites further protracted litigation.

 

            In fact, the report actually exacerbates the situation.

By placing such heavy reliance on incomplete data from Puget

Sound jurisdictions presented by the City, the report effec-

tively departs from the stipulated comparisons under RCW

41.56.460(c).  Moreover, the use of such incomplete data from

much smaller jurisdictions in this proceeding simply broadens

the scope of the evidence the parties will be compelled to

produce in their next round of litigation two years hence.

 

Lt. John Carson,

Association Partison

Arbitrator

 You are being directed to the most recent version of the statute which may not be the version considered at the time of the judgment.